BOSTON COLLEGE
LAW REVIEW
VOLUME XXIV
JULY
1983
NUMBER 4
THE JOINT COMMISSION ON ACCREDITATION OF
HOSPITALS: PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
AND THE PUBLIC INTEREST
TIMOTHY STOLTZFUS JOST
*
Recent months have seen a flurry of books and articles examining the
relative merits of government regulation or market competition as means of ad-
dressing perceived problems in the health care industry.' The primary focus of
• B.A. 1970, University of California, Santa Cruz, ,J.D. 1975, University of Chicago,
Assistant Professor, The Ohio State University College of Law. The author wishes to thank Peter
Gerhart, Thomas Christoffel, Gregory Travalio, Arthur Greenbaum, and Ruth Stoltzfus Jost,
who commented on earlier drafts; my research assistants Mark Toledo, David Penning
-
ton, Janet
Kater and Mike Mueller; and M. Margaretann Newton who helped process these words.
' For a sampling of the large and growing literature of the health care regulation-
competition debate see, generally criticizing regulation and favoring competition or market
reform: A. ENTHOVEN, HEALTH PLAN (1980) (hereinafter cited as ENTHOVEN, HEALTH PLAN);
M. FELDSTEIN, HOSPITAL COSTS AND HEALTH INSURANCE (1981); C. HAVIGHURST,
DEREGULATING THE HEALTH CARE INDUSTRY (1982) (hereinafter cited as HAVIGHURST,
DEREGULATION); F. SLOAN & B. STEINWALD, INSURANCE, REGULATION, AND HOSPITAL
COSTS (1980); Blumstein & Sloan,
"Redefining Government's Role in Health Care: Is a Dose of Competi-
tion What the Doctor Should Order?,"
34 VAND. L. REV. 849 (1981); Blumstein & Zubkoff,
Public
Choice in Health: Problems, Politics and Perspectives on Formulating National Health Policy,
4,J.
HEALTH
POL., POL'Y & L. 382 (1979); Bovbjerg,
Competition versus Regulation in Medical Care: An Overdrawn
Dichotomy,
34 VAND.
L.
REV. 965 (1981); Enthoven,
A Competitive Strategy,
304 NEW ENG.
J.
MED.
109 (1980); Enthoven,
Consumer Choice Health Plan,
298 NEW ENG.
J.
MED. 709 (1978);
Havighurst,
Competition in Health Services: Overview, Issues, and Answers,
34 VAND. L. REV. 1117
(1981) (hereinafter cited as Havighurst,
Competition);
Havighurst & Blumstein,
Coping with
Quality/Cost Trade-Offs in Medical Care: The Role of PSRO's,
70 Nw. U. L. REV. 6 (1975); Mc-
Clure,
Implementing a Competitive Medical Care System Through Public Policy, 7
J.
HEALTH POL.,
POL'Y & L. 2
(1982) (hereinafter cited as McClure,
Implementing);
McClure,
Structure and Incentive
Problems
in
Economic Regulation of Medical Care, 59 MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q. 107 (1981)
(hereinafter cited as McClure,
Structure);
Noll,
The Consequences of Public Utility Regulation of
Hospitals in
CONTROLS ON HEALTH CARE 25 (Institute of Med. ed., 1975); Pollard,
The Essential
Role of Anti-Trust in a Competitive Market for Health Services,
59 MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q. 256
(1981); generally favoring regulation or counselling caution as to procompetitive reform: Brown,
Competition and Health Cost Containment: Cautions and Conjecture,
59 MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q. 145
(1981); Dunham, Morone & White,
Restoring Medical Markets: Implications for the Poor, 7
J.
HEALTH POL., POL'Y &
L. 488 (1982); Ginzberg,
Procompetition in Health Care: Policy or Fable,
60
MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q. 386 (1982); Marmor, Boyer & Greenberg,
Medical Care and Pro-
Competitive Reform,
34 VAND. L. REV.. 1003 (1981); Rosenblatt,
Health Care, Markets, and
Democratic Values,
34 VAND. L. REV. 1067 (1981); Sigelman,
Palm Reading the Invisible Hand: A
Critical Examination of Pro-Competitive Reform Proposals,
6 J. HEALTH POL., POL'Y & L. 578 (1982);
835
836
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol.
24:835
this debate has been the problem of the high and rapidly rising cost of health
care.'
Market reform advocates argue that the excessive cost of health care is
largely attributable to structural problems in the health care delivery system
and health insurance industry, as well as to government policies that perversely
impede competition.' They contend that health care costs can best be con-
trolled by reintroducing competition into the health care sector through anti-
trust enforcement,
4
reform of health care delivery and health insurance,' and
alteration or elimination of anticompetitive government policies and
programs.' They reject direct command and control regulation as a means of
regulating cost,' arguing that it has not worked when tried,' and indeed cannot
work because of basic failures in the regulatory model.'
Vladeck,
The Market and Regulation: The Case for Regulation,
59 MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q 209
(1981); Weiner,
Reflections on Cost Containment Strategies,
59 MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q. 269 (1981)
(hereinafter cited as Weiner,
Reflections);
Weiner,
Governmental Regulation of Health Care: A Response
to Some Criticisms Voiced by Proponents of a "Free Market, "
4 AM. J. L. & MED. 15 (1978) (hereinafter
cited as Weiner,
Governmental);
and collections of essays: AMERICAN MEDICAL ASSOCIATION,
NATIONAL COMMISSION ON THE COSTS OF MEDICAL CARE
(1978);
HOSPITAL COST CONTAIN-
MENT
(M. Zubkoff, I. Raskin & R. Hanft eds. 1978); NATIONAL HEALTH INSURANCE (M. Pau-
ly ed. 1980); and A NEW APPROACH TO ECONOMICS OF HEALTH CARE,
M.
Olson ed. 1981
(hereinafter cited as NEW APPROACH).
2
See, e.g.,
ENTHOVEN, HEALTH PLAN,
supra
note 1, at xv-xvii; HAVIGHURST,
DEREGULATING,
supra
note I, at 25; Blumstein & Sloan,
supra
note 1, at 853; Bovbjerg,
supra
note I, at 965; Marmor,
supra
note 1, at 1003; Sigelman,
supra
note I, at 578. Throughout this
article "health care" will refer to care or treatment that promotes or restores human health;
"medical care" will refer more narrowly to care provided by physicians in accord with traditional
medical models.
3
See, e.g.,
ENTHOVEN, HEALTH PLAN,
supra
note 1, at 16-32; Blumstein & Sloan,
supra
note 1, at 856-58; Bovbjerg,
supra
note 1, at 967-73, 980-93; Havighurst,
Competition, supra
note 1, at 1120-25; Cohodes,
Where You Stand Depends on Where You Sit: Musings on
the
Regula-
tion/Competition Dialogue, 7
J.
HEALTH POL., POLY & L.
54, 55-61 (1982); Havighurst & Blum-
stein,
supra
note 1, at 9-30; McClure,
Structure, supra
note 1, at 139-41.
4
See,
,
Blumstein & Sloan, supra note 1, at 908-24; Havighurst,
A Comment: The
Anti-Trust Challenge to Professionalism,
41 MD. L. REV. 30 (1981); Havighurst,
Competition, supra
note 1, at 1148-49; Pollard,
supra
note 1, at 260-66.
See, e.g.,
ENTHOVEN, HEALTH PLAN,
supra
note 1; HAVIGHURST, DEREGULATING,
supra note 1, at 381-434; Bovbjerg,
supra
note 1, at 976-80; Cohodes,
supra
note 3, at 65-67; Mar-
mor, Boyer & Greenberg,
supra
note 1, at 1016-21.
See, e.g. ,
HAVIGHURST, DEREGULATING,
supra note
1, at 92-96; Blumstein & Sloan,
supra
note 1, at 867-86; McClure,
Structure, supra
note I, at 139-41.
7
See, e.g.,
ENTHOVEN, HEALTH PLAN,
supra
note 1, at 93-114; HAVIGHURST, DE-
REGULATING,
Supra
note 1, at 25-50; Blumstein & Zubkoff,
supra
note 1, at 387-93; McClure,
Im-
plementing, supra
note 1, at 17.20; McClure,
Structure, supra
note 1, at 139-42. As used in this arti-
cle command/control regulation is government regulation that relies on direct enforcement of
regulatory commands, as opposed to, e.g., use of incentives to encourage compliance.
3
See, e.g.,
Blumstein
&
Sloan,
supra
note 1, at 870-80; SLOAN & STEtNWALD,
supra
note 1, at 167-75, 193-96; Steinwald & Sloan,
Regulatory Approaches to Hospital Cost Containment: A
Synthesis of the Empirical Evidence
in NEW APPROACH,
supra
note 1, at 274.
9
See, e.g.,
ENTHOVEN, . HEALTH PLAN,
supra
note 1, at 110-13; P. FELDSTEIN,
HEALTH CARE ECONOMICS, 235-42 (1979); McClure,
supra
note 1, at 117-41; Noll,
supra
note 1,
at 28-47.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
837
On the other hand, defenders of regulation (some of whom would rather
be identified as skeptics of competitive reform)" pOint to the modest successes
of some forms of health care regulation" or argue for new forms of public inter-
vention more responsive to public values." They reject competitive alterna-
tives as inappropriate to and inconsistent with the basic nature of the health
care industry,'
3
as conceptually flawed," and, as unresponsive to basic politi-
cal values which regulation protects, such as public accountability and promo-
tion of distributional equity."
It is not surprising that this debate has focused on the issue of health care
costs. Recent increases in health care expenditures have been substantial, not
only in absolute terms," but also relative to the general inflation rate" and to
expenditures for other goods and services." Increases in government expendi-
tures on health care have also been dramatic and highly visible."
This focus on costs, however, has overshadowed a more traditional con-
cern of health care policy: the quality of health care. To the extent that advo-
cates of procompetitive market reform address the issue of quality, they do so
in disparate fashion. Some argue that increased competition would improve
quality by making health care delivery more efficient and eliminating excessive
and iatrogenic care.
2
° Others see a continuing minimalist role for regulation to
assure that basic standards of quality are maintained.
2
' Some theorize that as
the health care market becomes competitive a variety of levels of quality of care
" See, e.g.,
Rosenblatt,
supra
note 1, at 1069.
" Weiner,
Relectians, supra
note 1, at 274-75.
12
See generally
Rosenblatt,
supra
note 1, at 1069, 1108-14.
" See, e.g.,
Luft, On
the Potential Failure of Good Ideas: An Interview with the Originator•of
Murphy's Law, 7 J.
HEALTH POL., POLY & L. 45 (1982); Marmor, Boyer & Greenberg, supra
note 1, at 1011-26; Rosenblatt,
supra
note 1, at 1078-88; Sigelman,
supra
note 1, at 583.87;
Vladeck,
supra
note
1,
at 210-12.
" See, e.g.,
Brown,
supra
note
1,
at 174-87; Weiner,
Reflections, supra
note 1, at 287-93.
See, e.g.,
Dunham, Morone & White,
supra
note 1; Rosenblatt,
supra
note 1, at
1108-14; Sigelman,
supra
note 1, at 587-600; Vladeck,
supra
note 1, at 212-14; Vladeck,
The
Limits of Regulation: Implications of Alternative Models for the Health Sector
in TOWARD A NATIONAL
HEALTH CARE POLICY, 107, 137-40, 144-45
(K.
Friedman & S. Rakov eds. 1977).
16
National Health expenditures have increased from $26.9 billion in 1960 to $74.7
billion in 1970 to $286.8 billion in 1981. 4 HEALTH CARE FINANCING REV., Sept. 1982, at
19-20.
17
For the 12 month period ending March, 1982, medical care prices increased at a rate
of 11.4%. The consumer price index, all items, increased at a rate of 9.5%.
Health Care Financing
Trends,
June 1982, at 21.
18
Health care expenditures consumed 5.3% of the gross national product in 1960;
7.5% in 1970; 9.8% in 1981, 4 HEALTH CARE FINANCING REV.,
Sept.
1982,
at
19-21.
" Government expenditures for health programs have increased from $10.8 billion in
1965 to 122.53 billion in 1981.
Id.
at 31-32. In 1981 they constituted 42.75% of all health care ex-
penditures.
Id.
at 27. Health care expenditures currently consume more than 10% of the federal
budget, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management & Budget,
Budget of the United
States Government, Fiscal Year 1983,
3-34 (1972).
2
° See, e.g. ,
Enthoven,
Shattuck Lecture: Cutting Costs Without Cutting the Quality of Care,
298
NEW ENG.
J.
MED. 1229 (1978).
21 See, e.g.,
Havighurst,
Competition, supra
note 1, at 1.140; Noll, supra
note 1, at 46.
838
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
could emerge, offering consumers a greater range of choices." Finally, a few
assert that high health care costs may be the direct result of reliance on ex-
cessively high quality medical care (or perhaps on excessively intensive medical
care, inappropriately identified as of high quality)." Defenders of regulation
have even less to say on the issue of quality, though some fault advocates of
competition for an excessively narrow and economic reductionist view of
quality .
24
There are a number of reasons why health care quality and methods of
quality control ought to be at the center of the competition/regulation debate.
For market reform advocates the following issues of health care quality ought
seriously to be•considered. First, the ultimate success of a competitive reform
strategy may turn largely on whether the public perceives competition as main-
taining or threatening the quality of health care." Second, quality issues have
long been a focus of command and control regulation
;
26
if market reform advo-
cates depend on a critique of regulatory failures, analysis of regulation of quali-
ty should be a fruitful ground for inquiry. Finally, self-regulation has been a
pervasive form of quality control in the health care sector;" and some have
22
See, e.g.,
HAVIGHURST, DEREGULATING,
supra
note 1,
at
305-08.
23
See, e.g. ,
Blumstein and Havighurst,
supra
note 1, at 20-38; Zubkoff and Blumstein,
The Medical Market Place: Health Policy Formulation in Consideration of Economic Structure
in II
AMERICAN MEDICAL ASSOCIATION, supra note 1, at 88-89.
24
Rosenblatt,
supra
note 1, at 1091-1108.
23
A frequent comment of observers of the health care market is that consumers are
more concerned about the quality (or at least the effectiveness) of care they receive than about
cost. Blumstein & Sloan,
supra
note 1, at 857; Bovbjerg,
supra
note
1,
at 972; Mechanic,
Some
Dilemmas in Health Care Policy,
59 MILLBANK MEM. FUND Q. 1, 3 (1981). Some attribute this to
the prevalence
of third
party payments that anesthetizes patients to the cost implications of health
care decisions. Blumstein & Sloan,
supra
note 1, at 856-57; HAVIGHURST, DEREGULATING,
supra
note 1, at 83-84. While there is undoubtedly a great deal of truth in this, it is likely that con-
sumers would remain vitally concerned about the quality of health care even if procompetitive
reforms were to be fully implemented.
26
Physician licensing laws, to maintain the quality of practitioners, have existed in the
United States since the colonial period and were enacted in all states by 1895. DERBYSHIRE,
MEDICAL LICENSURE AND DISCIPLINE IN THE UNITED STATES 3-8 (1969). The licensure of
health care institutions to assure quality came later, but was common by the middle of this cen-
tury. Lander,
Licensing of Health Care Facilities,
in LEGAL ASPECTS OF HEALTH POLICY: ISSUES
AND TRENDS, 130-33 (R. Roemer & G. McKray eds. 1980). Regulation aimed at cost control, in
contrast, is much more recent. The first state certificate of need law was enacted by New York in
1964.
The
federal government enacted the 1122 Health Planning Program (P.L. 92-603, Title
II
S
221(a)) 86 Stat. 1386 (codified at 42 U.S.C. 4,1320a-1 (1976)) in 1972, and P.L. 93-641 (86
Stat. 2225 (codified at 42 U.S.C. 4 300k-300t (1976)), making certificate of need and health plan-
ning programs ubiquitous, in 1974, D. SALKEVER & T. BICE, HOSPITAL CERTIFICATE OF NEED
CONTROLS: IMPACT ON INVESTMENT, COSTS, AND USE 3, 4 (1979). Professional Standards
Review Organizations were established in 1972. 42 U.S.C. S 1320c-1320c-19 (1976 & Supp. IV,
1980). Prospective rate review programs date from around 1970 (most existing programs having
been established in the mid 1970's). Coelen & Sullivan,
An Analysis
of the Effects of Perspective Reim-
bursement
Programs on Hospital Expenditures,
2 HEALTH CARE FIN. REV., Winter 1981, 1, 2.
" Medical associations play a prominent role in licensing and disciplining physicians in
a number of states. F.
GRADA
N.
MARTI, PHYSICIANS' LICENSURE AND DISCIPLINE,
191-200
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
839
argued that self-regulation may be anti-competitive." Self-regulation based
quality control should, therefore, be subjected to close scrutiny by those who
favor the promotion of competition.
Defenders of regulation also ought to be concerned about quality control.
Just as critics of regulation may look to the effects of quality regulation to
establish their theories of regulatory failure, so defenders of regulation may
there find evidence of regulatory successes. Further, they legitimately may
challenge advocates of market reform to state how adequate quality of health
care will be guaranteed if current regulatory structures are swept aside. Final-
ly, the values of public accountability and distributional equity to which
defenders of regulation express allegiance, are, if anything, more relevant to
concerns of health care quality than to cost control.
This article examines the Joint Commission on Accreditation of Hospitals
(JCAH or Commission), the organization which has primary responsibility for
regulating the quality of care provided in American hospitals, and to a lesser
extent, that provided in nursing homes and other health care facilities. This in-
stitution is of particular relevance to the competition-regulation debate for
several reasons. First, the institutional medical (hospital and nursing home)
sector consumes a majority of health care expenditures and has been a major
offender in the dramatic health care cost inflation of recent years." It is also the
sector that consumes the vast majority of governmental funds expended on
health care.
30
Second, the JCAH is a private institution governed by represen-
tatives of hospitals and physicians, the participants in the health care industry
who have the most to lose from competition, and thus should be of particular
interest to those who seek to identify and eliminate impediments to competition
in the health care industry. Third, the JCAH is a private, non-governmental
entity, which wields considerable governmental authority. Those who defend
public regulation principally because of its responsiveness to public values
(1979). Certification of medical specialists is a totally private, intraprofessional function.
Id.
at
81; Grad,
The Antitrust Laws and Professional Discipline in Medicine,
1978 DUKE L.J. 443, 472-77.
Medical schools arc accredited by the Liaison Committee on Medical Education and hospitals
and nursing homes by the Joint Commission on Accreditation of Hospitals, both of which are
private, intraprofessional regulatory bodies. Professional Standards Review Organizations,
authorized by federal law to review utilization and quality of services delivered recipients of
federal medical benefits, are private peer review organizations composed of medical profes-
sionals. Control over staff privileges in hospitals, another form of professional self-regulation, is
significantly controlled by physicians.
Id.
at 468-72.
28
See
Pollard,
supra
note 1, at 265-66; HAVIGHURST, DEREGULATING,
supra
note 1, at
89-91.
28
Hospital and nursing home care consumed $132.2 of the $255 billion spent on per-
sonal health care in 1981. 4 HEALTH CARE FIN. REV., Sept. 1982, at 20. In the twelve month
period ending March 1981, the cost of hospital care increased at a rate of 14.1%, compared to a
10.7% increase for medical care generally.
4
HEALTH CARE FINANCING TRENDS, June 1982 at
13.
3
° Federal and state expenditure for hospital and nursing home care in 1981 constituted
$77.7
billion of the $102.9 billion government spent on personal health care. 4 HEALTH CARE
FIN. REV., Sept, 1982 at 27.
840
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol.
24:835
must examine seriously whether this particular private regulator is defensible
at all.
An examination of JCAH may also be of interest beyond its relevance to
health policy. The Reagan Administration, in a dramatic departure from the
policies of its predecessors, has proposed a regulatory reform policy that relies
on private voluntary standards for government regulation without any require-
ment for procedural safeguards to assure due process within the standard set-
ting organizations, or any review mechanism to protect the public or com-
petitors.
3
' In that JCAH is a source of voluntary standards, scrutiny of its ef-
fects on consumers, competitors and the public may shed light on the wisdom
of this policy.
After describing the organization and history of JCAH in section I, this
article in sections II and III analyzes JCAH standards and accreditation pro-
grams in light of economic analysis of standardization and information. Sec-
tion IV evaluates the efficacy of governmental standardization and accredita-
tion of the medical care industry as compared to JCAH standardization and ac-
creditation, and also considers whether JCAH should be made to function like
a public entity. The final section, section V, discusses legal tools that could be
used to reform or supplement JCAH in response to public quality and cost con-
cerns. In particular, section V considers the application of the Sherman An-
titrust Act to JCAH standards and accreditation, and also touches upon tort
law, federal Medicare law, and the non-delegation doctrine as means of con-
trolling JCAH.
I. THE
JOINT COMMISSION ON ACCREDITATION OF HOSPITALS
A.
Description
The JCAH is an Illinois Not For Profit Corporation headquartered in
Chicago. It is governed by a board composed of twenty-two commissioners"
appointed by the members of JCAH:" three by the American College of Physi-
cians (ACP); three by the American College of Surgeons (ACS); one by the
American Dental Association (ADA); seven by the American Hospital
Association (AHA); and seven by the American Medical Association (AMA).
34
An additional Commissioner is appointed by the Commission to serve as a
public member.
35
The Commissioners meet at least three times a year,
36
and
designated representatives of the constituent members meet at least once a
year."
" See
Proposed Revision to OIVIB circular A-119, 47 Fed. Reg. 16, 919 (1982).
33
BYLAWS
OF THE
JOINT
COMMISSION ON ACCREDITATION OF HOSPITALS,
art.
VI, §
1 (1982).
" Id.
at art. IV, § 1.
34
Id.
at art. VI, S 1.
35
Id.
36
Id.
at VI, § 7,
" Id. at art. V,
1.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
841
The purposes of the Commission, as stated in Article One of its by-laws
are:
(a) to establish standards for the operation of hospitals and other
health-related facilities and services;
(b) to conduct survey and accreditation programs that will encourage
members of the health professions, hospitals, and other health-
related facilities and services voluntarily to:
(1)
promote high quality of care in all aspects in order to give pa-
tients the optimum benefits that medical. science has to offer,
(2)
apply certain basic principles of physical plant safety and
maintenance, and of organization and administration of
functions for efficient care of the patient,
(3)
maintain the essential services in the facilities through coordi-
nated effort of the organized staffs and the governing body of
the facilities;
(c) to recognize compliance with standards by issuance of certificates
of accreditation;
(d) to conduct programs of education and research and publish the
results thereof which will further the other purposes of the corpo-
ration .. 38
The accreditation of hospitals is the most publicly visible, and probably the
most important, function of the JCAH.
39
JCAH also, however, accredits child,
adolescent, and adult psychiatric facilities; alcoholism and drug abuse facili-
ties;" community mental health service programs;“ long-term care facilities;
42
and ambulatory health care services."
Accreditation decisions are based on standards developed by members
of the Commission's four Professional Technical Advisory Committees
(PTAC 's)
44
and JCAH staff, and approved by the Board of Commissioners.'"
38
Id.
at art. I.
38
See
JCAH, ACCREDITATION MANUAL FOR HOSPITALS (hereinafter cited as AMH)
(1982).
48
See
JCAH, CONSOLIDATED STANDARDS MANUAL FOR CHILD, ADOLESCENT, AND
ADULT PSYCHIATRIC, ALCOHOLISM, AND DRUG ABUSE FACILITIES (1981).
41
See
JCAH, PRINCIPLES FOR ACCREDITATION OF COMMUNITY MENTAL HEALTH
SERVICES PROGRAMS
(1979).
42
See
JCAH, ACCREDITATION MANUAL FOR LONG-TERM CARE FACILITIES
(1980).
44
See
JCAH, ACCREDITATION MANUAL FOR AMBULATORY HEALTH CARE
(1982).
JCAH is also currently considering the development of accreditation programs for hospices and
for facilities for the developmentally disabled.
See Pilot Test of Proposed Hospice Standards Conducted,
JCAH PERSPECTIVES, July-Aug
1982, at 5 cited as
Director Appointed to Develop Hospice Standards
and Guide,
JCAH PERSPECTIVES, Nov-Dec 1981, at 4.
* 4
The PTAC's are responsible for the hospital, ambulatory health care, long-term care
and psychiatric facilities accreditation programs. JCAH, MILESTONES OF PROGRESS,
A
COR-
PORATE REPORT 22, 23 (1962) (hereinafter cited as MILESTONES).
4
' AMH,
supra
note 39, at xi;
See
Affeldt,
JCAH and Voluntary Accreditation,
39 J. ORAL
SURG.
Feb. 1981, at 94, 95.
842
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
These standards undergo a process of continual review and revision based on
input from the PTAC's, accredited institutions, and health care profession-
als." The PTAC's include representatives of health care organizations in addi-
tion to the members of the JCAH.
47
The Board is also advised by a Policy Ad-
visory Committee (PAC) composed of representatives of the PTAC's,
representatives of organizations involved in the provision of health related serv-
ices, representatives of other national organizations with interests similar to
those of JCAH, and selected individuals."
Accreditation by the JCAH is voluntary. Facilities must request a survey
by JCAH staff" who, based on the survey results, recommend to a Committee
of the Commissioners for or against accreditation.
5
° To be JCAH accredited a
facility must substantially comply with the JCAH standards as a whole, but
need not comply, nor even substantially comply, with every JCAH standard.
5
'
Facilities denied accreditation by the committee may request review by an ap-
peals hearing panel appointed by the president of JCAH, and, ultimately if
necessary, review by the Board of Commissioners or by a committee of the
Board." Most facilities that are surveyed receive accreditation: in a recent
survey only one percent were denied full or provisional accreditation."
JCAH does not view accreditation as a public regulatory program, rather
JCAH identifies itself as a consultant, paid by and responsible to the medical
care industry." It acts as a quality control consultant to the hospitals that it in-
46
AMH,
supra
note 39, at x; Affeldt,
supra
note 45, at 95; McCleary,Joint
Commission on
Accreditation of Hospitals: Twenty-Five Years of Promoting Improved Health Care Services,
34 AM. J. OF
HOSP. PHARM. 951, 953 (1977).
" MILESTONES,
supra
note 44, at 22, 23. For example, the hospital accreditation pro-
gram PTAC includes representatives of the American Academy of Family Physicians, the
American Academy of Pediatrics, the American College of Hospital Administrators, the Ameri-
can College of Obstetricians and Gynecologists, the American Nurses Association, the American
Psychiatric Association, the American Society of Anesthesiologists, the Association of American
Medical Colleges, the Association of Operating Room Nurses, and the College of American
Pathologists, and representatives of the five member programs.
46
Id.
at 22;
Reorganization Sets Future for Voluntary Accreditation,
PERSPECTIVES ON AC-
CREDITATION, Mar.-Apr. 1979, 1, at 6 (hereinafter
"Reorganization").
42
AMH, supra note 39, at xix.
Id. at xxi,
xxii, 199-200.
" Id. at
xvii. Schlicke,
Dots the Joint Commission Have a Future,
63 AM. C. OF SURG.,
Apr. 1978, at 7, 11.
52
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xxii, 200-04.
53
Affeldt,
Voluntary Accreditation in Regulating Health Care: The Struggle for Control
(ed. A.
Levin), 33
PROC.
ACAD. POL. SCI. 182, 189 (1980).
See also Nursing Home Survey and Certification:
Assuring Quality Care, Hearings, Senate Special Comm. on Aging
97th Cong. 2d Sess. (1982) (here-
inafter cited as
Senate Hearings)
(20 hospitals denied JCAH accreditation in 1981). Hospitals can
either receive full three year accreditation or accreditation with contingencies requiring follow-up
by progress-reports or on-site visits. Affeldt,
What to Expect from New Contingency System,
56 HOSP.
Oct. 16, 1982, at 60.
54
Senate
Hearings, supra
note 53, at 103 (testimony of John Affeldt, JCAH President).
Physician
Training Facilities and Health Maintenance Organization: Hearings before the Subcomm. on Health
of the Senate Committee
on Labor & Publ c _Welfare,
92nd Cong., 2d Sess. 1990 (1972); (Statement of
John
Porterfield, JCAH director); Crosby,
Accreditation
and
Associated Quality Assurance Efforts,
13
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
843
spects and provides with confidential reports of deficiencies." In addition, it
provides essential information to physicians and other private certification en-
tities, who rely on JCAH accreditation.
56
Despite the fact that JCAH considers
itself a private consultant, it plays a major role in government regulatory pro-
grams. Indeed, although accreditation is in theory voluntary, hospital ac-
creditation is either explicitly or implicitly a requirement for participation in
many private or public licensing, certification and financing programs. For ex-
ample, the federal government relies heavily upon JCAH accreditation for cer-
tifying health care facilities for participation in the Medicare program. Section
1864 of the Social Security Act
57
permits the Secretary of Health and Human
Services (HHS) to enter into agreements with state health departments to
survey hospitals to determine their compliance with Medicare regulations. But
Section 1864 provides," as an alternative, that if an institution is accredited as
a hospital by the JCAH and the hospital authorizes JCAH to release to the
Secretary (on a confidential basis) a copy of the most recent accreditation
survey of the hospital, then such hospital shall, subject to minor exceptions,"
be deemed to comply with Medicare certification requirements for hospitals.
These hospitals are said to have "deemed" certification status. JCAH is
responsible for monitoring quality in deemed status facilities for the Medicare
program, subject only to verification inspections done by state agencies ran-
domly and on the basis of substantial complaints.
6
°
PROF. PSYCHOLOGY 132, 133,
(1982); Ellis,
Critical Challenges Lie Ahead for New JCAH President,
HOSP. MED. STAFF,
Oct.
1977, at 34, 41; Porterfield,
TheJCAH: An Assessment of Strengths, Needs,
Intentions,
5 HosP. MED. STAFF, Feb. 1976, 19, 20;
Punch, JCAH Says it's as Tough as Government
Surveyors,
12 MOD. HEALTH CARE, Sept. 1982, at 38, 40; Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 12,
but cf.
JCAH's mission and scope statement, MILESTONES,
supra
note 44, at 25 (asserting JCAH's mis-
sion to be to "secure for the public an excellence of health care consistent with social and
economic considerations.")
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xxi, xxii, xxiv.
JCAH also operates educational programs to acquaint medical professionals with
JCAH accreditation standards, MILESTONES,
supra
note 44, at 11,
JCAH Education Programs,
1982 Fall/Winter Calendar,
and conducts research,
see
MILESTONES,
supra
note 44, at 9.
" 42 U.S.C. S 1395aa(a) (1976 and Supp. IV, 1980).
56
42 U.S.C. S 1395bb (1976).
See also
42 C.F.R. 405.1902(a)(2) (1981). Under the
regulation a hospital need only authorize the release of the JCAH survey if the hospital is the sub-
ject of a validation survey.
59
Independent state inspection of accredited facilities is necessary for compliance with
utilization review requirements and with any additional requirements promulgated by the
Secretary of HHS higher or more specific than JCAH accreditation requirements. 42 U.S.C. S
1395bb (1976).
" The Secretary contracts with state survey agencies to inspect, on a random basis and
in response to substantial complaints, JCAH accredited facilities to validate the JCAH accredita-
tion, 42 C.F.R. 405.1901(e) (1981). If facilities are determined, upon state inspection, to be out
of compliance with one or more conditions of Medicare participation and a significant deficiency
is determined to exist, the hospital will no longer be deemed to meet the conditions of participa-
tion and will be subject to full review by the state agency survey. 42 C.F.R. S 405.1901(e)(4)(i)
(1981). A significant deficiency will not be determined to exist, however, if (1) JCAH accepts the
state survey agency findings of deficiencies and agrees to monitor their correction; (2) the state
agency does not justify to HHS the need for continued full review by the state agency; and (3)
844
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
While general hospitals are given the option of obtaining Medicare cer-
tification either through deemed status based on JCAH accreditation or inde-
pendent state agency survey, a psychiatric hospital generally must be accred-
ited by the JCAH to participate in the Medicare or Medicaid program.
61
Moreover, Section 1865 also provides that HHS may grant deemed status to
skilled nursing facilities and home health agencies to the extent that the Secre-
tary of HHS finds that JCAH accreditation provides "reasonable assurances"
that the provisions of the Medicare Act will be met by such institutions.
62
The
Secretary has, under this power, published proposed regulations to grant
deemed status to JCAH accredited skilled nursing homes,
63
though Congress
has passed two moratoria delaying the implementation of these proposed
regulations."
To varying degrees, thirty-eight states have also incorporated JCAH
standards or accreditation decisions into their licensing programs for health
care institutions.
65
A few states, by statute, regulation, or administrative fiat,
deem hospitals to meet state licensure requirements by virtue of their JCAH
accreditation.
66
Other states, by statute or regulation, permit, but do not re-
quire the licensure agency to license on the strength of JCAH accreditation.
67
JCAH in fact provides HHS with periodic reports of progress towards correction. 42 C.F.R. §
405.1901(e)(4)(ii) (1981). Moreover, if the deficiencies, individually or in combination, jeopard-
ize the health and safety of patients or seriously limit the provider's capacity to render adequate
care, or if the non-complying facility does not come into compliance within a reasonable period of
time, it may be terminated from Medicare participation. 42 C.F.R. 5 405.1905, 1907 (1981).
61
42 U.S.C. 55 1395x(1), 1396d(h) (1976). A "distinct part" of a nonaccredited
psychiatrist facility may be certified for medicare without JCAH accreditation if HHS deter-
mines that it meets requirements equivalent to those of JCAH. 42 U. S.C.5 1395 x (0(1976), 42
C.F.R. 405.1036 (1982). "Distinct part" certification can also be used to establish medicaid
eligibility for institutions for mental diseases for persons aged 65 and older, 42 C.F.R.
440.140(2) (1982), but not for institutions for mental diseases for persons aged 21 and younger.
62
42 U.S.C. 5 1395bb (1976).
63
47 Fed. Reg. 23404, (May 27, 1982) (to be codified at 42 C.F.R. 405, 431, 442, 489,
490).
64
Pub. L. No. 97-248 5 135, 96 Stat. 324, 375, places a six month moratorium on the
final promulgation of the rule to "provide opportunity for further review, revision or
withdrawal" of the proposed regulations, H.R. Rep. 97.760 97th Cong. 2d Sess. 441 (1982).
This moratorium has been extended 120 days by Pub. L. No. 276 § 146, 96 Stat. 1186, 1199
(1981).
See
Robinson,
Congress Stalls HHS Survey Proposal,
12 MOD. HEALTH CARE, Sept. 1982, at
38. Several Congressional hearings have reviewed the HHS proposal:
Department of Health and
Human Services Oversight, Hearings before the Subcomm. on Oversight and Investigations on the House Comm.
on Energy and Commerce,
97th Cong. 2d Sess. (1982);
NUrsing Home Inspections; New Jersey, Hearing
before House Select Comm. on Aging,
97th Cong. 2d Sess. (1982) (hereinafter cited as House hear-
ings);
Senate hearings, supra
note 53.
65
Telephone interview with Eleanor Wagner and Daniel Schuyler, attorneys for
JCAH (December 9, 1982).
See also
MILESTONES,
supra
note 44, at 7 (an earlier source stating 34
states rely on JCAH);
Senate hearings, supra
note 53, at 76 (36 states).
66
See, e.g.,
ALA. CODE 5 22-21-24 (Supp. 1982); ARIZ. REV. STAT. ANN. 5 36-401,
424 (West. Supp. 1982); N.M. STAT. ANN. 5 24-1-5 (1978); TEX. STAT. ANN. art. 4437h 4(a)
(Vernon Supp. 1982); NEV. ADMIN. CODE Part
11,
Chapt. II 5 9B.
67
CAL. HEALTH & SAFETY CODE 5
1282 (1979); OR. REV. STAT. 5 441.055(2) (1981).
California is reportedly abandoning cooperation with JCAH because of dissatisfaction with
JCAH performance.
See Plaintiff'
s and Plaintiff-Intervenor's Trial Brief, 8-10 submitted Oct. 26,
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
845
Still others rely on accreditation supplemented with some form of validation
program." Several states require licensed hospitals to meet certain specific
JCAH standards, the most common requirement being that hospitals comply
with JCAH medical staff privilege standards.
69
A few states require that state
mental hospitals or state university hospitals be JCAH accredited.
7
° Finally, at
least two states have insurance laws permitting private health insurance com-
panies to pay for specific forms of care only if the care was provided in a JCAH
accredited facility."
JCAH hospital accreditation is also relied on by the private health care
sector. JCAH accreditation is required for institutions to participate in some
Blue Cross plans." Some professional organizations limit membership to pro-
fessionals associated with JCAH accredited hospitals." Finally, JCAH accredi-
tation is effectively required for hospitals to be approved for residency pro-
grams." As a result of these factors, eighty percent of all acute care hospitals in
the United States are JCAH accredited," including virtually all hospitals with
more than twenty-five beds.
76
This is true despite the expense of "voluntary"
accreditation: hospitals must pay $250 plus $1,000 per surveyor per day for a
survey, a minimum of $4,250 and often much more."
B.
The Development of the JCAH
1. The American College of Surgeons Hospital. Standardization Program,
1912 Through 1951.
1982 in Wyatt v. Ireland, No. 3195-N (M.D. Ala.) (hereinafter cited as Wyatt Brief). (Wyatt v.
Ireland, is part of the ongoing Alabama mental hospital litigation,
see
Wyatt v, Strickney, 344 F.
Supp. 373 (M.D. Aka. 1972)
aff'd in part sub. nom.
Wyatt v. Aderholt, 503 F.2d 1305 (5th Cir.
1974). The JCAH has become involved because of a proposal of the defendants to permit JCAH
accreditation to substitute, in part, for the earlier system of monitoring imposed by the courts);
Senate hearings, supra
note 53, at 40 (testimony of Mildred Simmons, Deputy Director Cal. Dept.
of Health Services).
6
° VA. CODE 5 32.1.125.1(B) (1979); KAN. ADMIN. REGS. Art. 34 5 28-34-2, 28-34-3;
La. Admin. Reg. (Hosp.) 5 41.
69
FLA. STAT. ANN. 5
395.065 (West Supp. 1982). R.I. GEN LAWS 5 23-17-23 (1979);
VT. STAT. ANN. tit. 18 1905(9) (1968); N.H. ADMIN. CODE (Hosp) $ 2130.
OHIO REV. CODE ANN. § 5119.10
(Page 1981) represents one such statute.
" OHIO REV. CODE ANN. § 1739.061 (Page 1981) 3923.27 (Page 1970); OR. REV.
STAT. 5 743.412(4)(b), 743.557(2)(6) (1981).
" See
F. Hair, Hospital Accreditation: A Developmental Study of the Social Control of
Institutions, 204-09 (Ph.D. dissertation Vand. U. 1972); 1 COMPETITION
AMONG
HEALTH
PRACTITIONERS IV-11 (W.
Lazarus ed., 1981) (hereinafter cited as W. Lazarus). Schlicke,
American Surgery's Noblest Experiment,
106 ARCH. SURG. 379, 381 (1973). In 1972, 20 of the 75 Blue
Cross plans in the United States required or encouraged JCAH accreditation. F. Hair,
supra,
at
208.
" Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 381.
74
ESSEN'T'IALS
OF
ACCREDITED RESIDENCIES
IN
GRADUA'I'E MEDICAL EDUCATION §
1.4 in 1981-1982 DIRECTORY
OF
RESIDENCY TRAINING PROGRAMS.
75
Affeldt,
supra
note 45, at 95; Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 189,
Senate hearings, supra
note
53, at 78.
76
Affeldt,
supra
note 45, at 95; Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 189.
" Affeldt,
The Three Year Cycle,
55 HOSP., Dec. 16, 1981, at 69. Nursing homes pay
846
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
To understand fully the origins and development of JCAH, the history of
organized American health care delivery must be considered. The extensive,
indeed almost exclusive, reliance on large medical institutions which character-
izes the current health care delivery system is a quite recent development.
Though hospitals existed in the nineteenth century, they bore little resemb-
lance to the modern institution of the same name." Until late in the nineteenth
century a hospital was primarily a charitable institution that provided housing,
moral nurture, and health care for the worthy poor," usually for free." Middle
and upper class patients received medical care,- including surgery, in their own
homes and seldom entered hospitals.'"
During the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, however, the
organization of medical care changed rapidly and radically. Scientific and
technical developments, especially the development of antisepsis and asepsis,
made hospitals much safer and more attractive to the middle class," at the
same time that social changes were making home treatment less feasible."
With new technology came increases in hospital costs." In response, hospitals
began to charge for their care, and to permit physicians who practiced within
the hospital to charge for their services." All of this led to rapid growth. The
number of hospitals increased from 178 in 1873 to 4359 in 1909.
66
As the nature of the hospital was changing, so was the nature of the prac-
tice of medicine. In the nineteenth century most physicians were generalists."
Specialization for physicians, uncommon in the nineteenth century, developed
rapidly in the twentieth." Especially remarkable was the emergence of surgery
as a specialty practice. The discovery of antisepsis, following upon the earlier
discovery of anesthesia, made surgery safer and more common
;
89
the demand
$625 per surveyor per day.
Id.
'
13
G.
ROSEN,
FROM
MEDICAL POLICE TO SOCIAL MEDICINE: ESSAYS IN THE
HISTORY
OF HEALTH CARE
293-95 (1974);
REVERBY,
THE
SEARCH FOR THE HOSPITAL YARD-
STICK: NURSING
AND THE RATIONALIZATION OF
HOSPITAL
WORK IN HEALTH CARE IN
AMERICA:
ESSAYS
IN SOCIAL
HISTORY 206, 207-09 (S. Reverby & D. Rosner eds. 1979)
(hereinafter cited as
HEALTH CARE IN AMERICA);
Rosner,
Health Care for the "Truly Needy":
Nineteenth Century Origins of the Concept,
60
MILLBANK
MEM. FUND.
Q. 355, 372, 375 (1982);
Vogel,
The Transformation of
the
American Hospital 1850-1920
in
HEALTH CARE IN AMERICA, supra,
at 105-10.
78
Vogel,
supra
note 78, at 105-10.
88
Id. at
109.
8
Id. at
105.
°2
Id. at
111-13.
" Id. at
110-11.
84
Id. at
112.
" Rosner,
supra
note 78, at 378-79; Rosner,
Business at the Bedside: Health Care in
Brooklyn, 1890-1915,
in HEALTH CARE
IN
AMERICA, supra
note 78, at 122-28.
66
R.
STEVENS,
AMERICAN
MEDICINE
AND THE PUBLIC INTEREST
52 (1972).
67
Id.
at
43-49.
16
Id.
at 49, 50, 77-80.
89
death rate for abdominal and pelvic surgery
was
40% in the decade 1880-1890,
by 1900 it was
below
5%.
Id.
at 49, 78-80.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
847
for surgery increased greatly and surgeons' incomes grew rapidly.
9
° Though
surgeons increasingly relied on hospitals, the hospitals of the early twentieth
century continued to be organized poorly for the practice of surgery. Hospitals
lacked clinical laboratories, radiology, pathology, and other equipment and
services necessary for proper pre-operative and post-operative care." Inade-
quate medical records made it difficult to analyze the results of surgery."
Though surgical specialization and sub-specialization were becoming in-
creasingly common in the early twentieth century, it was hard for the public to
identify doctors qualified to perform surgery. General practitioners continued
to perform surgeries, as did many incompetent doctors who called themselves
surgeons." General practitioners could identify qualified surgeons, and refer
patients to them, but this arrangement often resulted in fee splitting, which was
costly and increasingly viewed as unprofessional conduct." Hospitals generally
made staff privileges - the privilege of admitting patients to and being
primarily responsible for patients within the hospital - available to any and all
physicians.
95
A closed staff system developed at this time in Britain, limiting
the practice of surgery to experienced specialists, but a similar system did not
develop in the United States."
The American College of Surgeons was organized in November 1912 in
an attempt to standardize and organize the practice of surgery." One of the
first tasks undertaken by the ACS was the standardization of hospital care. The
1912 Clinical Congress, at which the ACS was founded, adopted a resolution
calling for "some system of standardization of hospital work.
"
98
A committee,
established to study the improvement of hospital standards,
99
issued a report
recommending investigations, reports, and administrative procedures to im-
prove and standardize hospital care.'" In January of 1916, the ACS received a
$30,000 grant from the Carnegie Foundation to develop hospital standards,"'
and in October of the following year the first conference on hospital standardi-
zation was held.'" In December of 1917, a questionnaire was circulated to
L. DAVIS, FELLOWSHIP OF SURGEONS: A HISTORY
OF THE
AMERICAN COLLEGE
OF
SURGEONS 139 (1960).
91
Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 182;
Reorganization Sets Future of Voluntary Accreditation,
JCAH
PERSPECTIVES ON ACCREDITATION,' Mar.-Apr, 1979, at 2.
92
Affeldt,
Voluntary Accreditation, supra
note 53, at 182; L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 117,
204-05.
99
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 69-70; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 81.
94
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 87-88, 97-98, 137-42; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at
83-84.
" R. STEVENS, supra note 86, at 83.
96
Id.
at 82.
97
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 61-62, 69-70; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 86-87.
Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 183, L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 63, 475-76, F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 36; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 379.
99
The committee was directed by Dr. Ernest A. Codman. F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 36.
100
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 116, 117; F. Hair, supra note 72, at 37.
101
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 176; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 91.
102
L. DAVIS, supra note 90, at 207; F. Hair, supra note 72, at 45.
848
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
2711 hospitals in the United States and Canada,'" followed by a survey of 692
hospitals in 1918 and the same number in 1919.
104
The standards on which the
survey was based concentrated on the surgeon's needs in the physician-hospital
relationship. The standards required medical staff organization; limitation of
staff privileges to qualified physicians and surgeons; regular meetings of the
medical staff; accurate, complete and accessible medical records; and provision
of diagnostic and therapeutic facilities (including clinical laboratory and x-ray
facilities).
103
Of the 671 facilities of over 100 beds surveyed by the ACS, only 89
could comply with the requirements.'" To avoid embarrassment to the promi-
nent hospitals that had failed the standard examination, the list of approved
hospitals was burned the night before its scheduled presentation in October
1919.'
07
The shocking results of the 1919 survey added impetus to the interest of
the ACS in hospital standardization.'" On December 20, 1919, the Board of
Regents of the ACS established the Hospital Standardization Program (HSP)
the predecessor of the JCAH.
1
°
3
The HSP attempted to identify and recognize
efficiently organized hospitals with well-run diagnostic and therapeutic serv-
ices, and accurate and complete case records. In addition the HSP sought
regularly to analyze and audit hospital progress toward compliance with the
minimum HSP standards."° Like the earlier ACS standards, HSP standards
focused on the organization and suitability of the hospitals for physicians. The
HSP standards stressed self-regulation of the medical staff, but left ultimate re-
sponsibility for granting staff privileges with the hospital administration and
governing board."'
Between 1926 and 1941 the Manual for Hospital Standardization was re-
vised seven times and grew from an eighteen-page pamphlet to a 118 page
book."' By 1941, the minimum standard had been supplemented by sixteen
additional standards addressing not only the organization of physician care,
but also the physical plant, equipment, and administrative organization of the
hospital."
3
The HSP effort to bring about medical staff organization had some
fairly dramatic immediate results: between 1918 and 1935 the percentage of
hospitals with organized medical staffs increased from twenty percent to ninety
109
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 207; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 45.
104
L. DAVIS, supra note 90, at 222; F. Hair, supra note 72, at 45, 46.
105
The standards are reproduced at Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 184.
106
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 221; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 46.
187
L. DAVIS,
Supra
note 90, at 221; A. GERBER, THE GERBER REPORT 101-03 (1971);
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 46.
"
8
Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 184.
109
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 221; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 47; Affeldt,
supra
note 53,
at 184.
"
8
L. DAVIS, supra note 90, at 172-74, 489-90; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 47.
"
1
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 221; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 49; M. ROEMER & J.
FRIEDMAN, DOCTORS IN HOSPITALS 36-37 (1971).
"2
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 66.
19
Id.
at 66-67, 76-77.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
849
percent of hospitals surveyed.
E
4
Nevertheless, many hospitals continued to
rely on unqualified staff, and shortages of physicians brought about by World
War II further aggravated problems in upgrading the quality of hospital physi-
cians.
15
The ACS and its HSP were from the first opposed by many physicians."
6
The American Medical Association (AMA) which represented the broader
spectrum of physicians, had previously passed a resolution opposing distin-
guishing marks for specialists.'" Many physicians opposed the HSP as a threat
to their freedom of medical practice and resisted mandatory medical record
charting and routine use of diagnostic laboratory tests.'" The AMA declined
an invitation from the 1914 ACS Congress to take over HSP,"
9
in 1918 threat-
ened to establish its own hospital standardization program, and even organized
a rival hospital conference. Tension continued to exist between the AMA and
ACS throughout the first half of the twentieth century,'
2
° reflecting the dif-
ferences between the elite and well paid hospital-based surgeons, and the pre-
dominantly poorer community-based general practitioners."' The American
Hospital Association (AHA), and Catholic Hospital Association on the other
hand supported the HSP.'
22
2. The Founding and Early Years of the Joint Commission on Accreditation
of Hospitals 1951-1965
The 1940's saw further changes in the organization of the delivery of
medical care in the United States. Well-defined classifications for medical spe-
cialists developed in the armed forces during World War II,
123
and public sub-
sidies for graduate medical education under the GI Bill led to a rapid rise in
specialization during the 1940's and 1950's.
124
Hospital expansion was stimu-
lated by the Hospital Survey and Construction Act of 1946
125
(the Hill-Burton
Act) which made generous federal assistance available for hospital construc-
tion. The Hill-Burton program also changed the nature of hospital regulation.
It imposed a cut-off on Hill-Burton funds to any state that did not, by July 1,
1948, enact "legislation providing that compliance with minimum standards of
maintenance and operation shall be required" of hospitals assisted through the
Id.
at 78,
15
Id.
at 80-84.
"
6
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 79, 89-93, 113-15 and 130-32.
ul R. STEVENS,
Supra
note 86. at 89.
See also
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 131; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 34 (discussing the opposition of the AMA to the ACS).
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 205-06; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 42-43.
"
9
L. DAVIS, supra
note 90, at 158, 175; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 91.
ISO L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 230; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 128-29.
12L
See
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 133, 139; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 176-77 and
198.
122
L. DAVIS,
Supra
note 90, at 185, 206-07; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 43-44.
123
R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 298-99.
14
Id.
at 297, 299.
'
2
' Pub. L. No. 79-725, 60 Stat. 958 (Codified at 42 U.S.C. §§ 291-291n (1946)).
850
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol 24:835
Hill-Burton Act.
126
In response to the Hill-Burton minimum standards re-
quirement, the AHA, with the assistance of the American Public Welfare Asso-
ciation, developed a model licensing law.'" This bill, as modified by a larger
group convened by the Council of State Governments, became the model hos-
pital licensing act upon which most current state hospital licensing laws are
based.'" The Hill-Burton Act, therefore, led to a radical increase in state in-
terest in hospital licensure: whereas only twelve states licensed general hospi-
tals prior to 1945, twenty-six additional states enacted licensure laws between
1945 and 1950)
29
The growing complexity of hospital care and increasing number of hospi-
tals gradually overwhelmed the HSP. Until 1950, ACS had single-handedly
financed the HSP, principally from the dues of its members, spending two
million dollars on the HSP, during the thirty-one years of the HSP, including
$68,577.27 for the fiscal year 1949.
13
° In 1950, the new director of the ACS,
Paul R. Hawley, began to seek out alternatives for the management of the pro-
gram."' Because of past AMA coolness toward the HSP, Hawley turned first
to the AHA,'" which had considered initiating its own hospital standardiza-
tion program as early as 1943 but had not proceeded because of the existence of
the ACS program.'" The AHA offered to take over the standardization pro-
gram,
134
and on July 21, 1950 a committee of the ACS and AHA drafted an
agreement for transfer of the HSP.
139
The proposal for transfer was rejected by
the ACS Board of Regents on August 4, 1950, but on August 5, the AHA
Board of Trustees adopted a resolution to create its own standardization pro-
gram.
136
At this point, the AMA entered the fray, attacking AHA control over
hospital standardization as an attempt to "superimpose lay judgment on pro-
fessional knowledge and ability,'"" other medical association journals called
for a boycott of hospitals accredited by the AHA,'" and attacks on the ACS
standardization program within the AMA and the newly formed American
Academy of General Practice (AAGP) were revived.
139
126
42 U.S.C. § 291f(d) (1946).
17
Lander,
supra
note 26, at 131, A. SOMERS, HOSPITAL REGULATION: THE DILEMMA
OF PUBLIC POLICY 107 (1969).
123
Lander,
supra
note 26, at 131, A. Somers,
supra
note 127, at 107.
129
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 245.
"° L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 379, 380; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 99; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 380.
131
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 100.
132
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 381.
133
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 100.
134
Id.
at 101.
"' Id.
The transfer as proposed would have created a 25 member commission: 13
members (including the chairman) appointed from hospital trustees; 6 hospital administrators, 3
surgeons appointed by the ACS, and 3 physicians appointed by the ACP. L. DAVIS,
supra
note
90, at 382; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 101-02.
136
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 382, 383; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 102.
132
Editorial,
Inspection of Hospitals by
Hospitals,
1441 AM. MED. A.
394, 395 (1950).
138
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 105-06.
139 L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 383; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 108.
July 19831
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
851
In this context of strife and suspicion, efforts at cooperation nevertheless
were begun. On November 19, 1950, the AHA, AMA, ACS, and ACP agreed
tentatively to coordinate their efforts and attempt to establish a joint hospital
standardization program.'
4
° Characteristically, the meetings that followed
were "highlighted by tangential discussion, misstatement of facts, misunder-
standings of purposes, and evasive answers to pointed questions."141
The
AMA continued to take a dim view of the involvement of non-physicians in
hospital standardization. Continued discussions, however, finally resulted in
the proposal of a joint commission, with representation of six members each for
the AMA and AHA, three members each for the ACS and ACP and one mem-
ber to represent the Canadian Medical Association.
142
The Commission was to
be funded by each of the member groups in proportion to its representation,
with field inspection staff provided by the ACS and the AMA.
143
The proposed commission was quickly approved by the AHA, ACS and
ACP, but opposition continued within the AMA.
144
The AAGP led the opposi-
tion, insisting upon either a standardization program conducted solely by the
AMA, or independent representation for itself on any joint commission."' The
AMA house of delegates finally approved the formation of the Joint Commis-
sion on September 16, 1951, with a proviso admonishing the AMA to continue
to press for strengthened representation on the Commission for the AMA, and
for less representation for the AHA.
146
The JCAH held its organizational
meeting on December 15, 1951.
147
Although JCAH adopted the ACS standards without alteration, it paid
more attention to specific aspects of the hospital medical program: medical
records, staff appointments, clinical pathological conferences, and tissue
review.
118
This was seen as interference in medical practice and provoked some
opposition from physicians.
19
Continued opposition from the General Practice
section of the AMA necessitated AMA committees which in 1956 and again in
1961 and 1963 investigated the JCAH, each time recommending continued
AMA participation .
15
°
14°
L.
DAvIS,
supra
note 90, at 343, 500; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 109.
"' L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 384.
'
42
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 386. The Canadians withdrew in 1959 when they
founded their own accrediting commission, Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 380.
F, Hair,
supra
note 72, at 112.
144
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 386, 387.
144
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 113;
Joint Commission is Proposed,
76
MOD.
HOSP.,
June
1951, at 70;
Looking Forward,
76 MOD. HOSP., May 1951, at 49.
'
46
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 116. (The AHA and AMA have continued to have an equal
number of representatives on the Commission and AMA efforts to change this appear to have
been abandoned).
147
Id.
at 117.
148
Id.
at 119. The hospitals accredited by the ACS were also automatically accorded ac-
creditation by the JCAH, L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 387.
149
F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 119-22,
15°
Id.
at 122-32.
852
BOSTON COLLEGE
LAW
REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
The early 1960's saw changes in the JCAH. In 1961, JCAH developed its
own paid survey staff permitting an end to reliance on the field staff of the ACS
and AMA."' In 1964, the JCAH began to charge fees for its inspection pro-
gram, reducing the financial burden of its members.
152
Then, in 1965, the
JCAH expanded its scope, assuming responsibility for nursing home accredita-
tion, and adding commissioners to represent the American Nursing Home
Association and American Association of Homes for the Aging.
153
JCAH also
expanded by adding a program to accredit psychiatric facilities in 1960 and a
program for accreditation of rehabilitation facilities in 1967.
154
3. The Joint Commission and the Medicare Program: 1965-1975
With the advent of Medicare in 1965, JCAH was radically changed from a
private, voluntary accreditation program to an agency with a major role in
public
health care regulation and financing. Though national health insurance
had been a popular issue for much of this century, legislation which directly
spawned the current Medicare and Medicaid programs was introduced only in
the late 1950' s."
5
Early drafts of this legislation paid minimal attention to con-
trolling the quality of health care services which
the new government funds
would purchase.
156
Subsequent bills, however, began to contemplate quality
control through the use of existing accrediting agencies. A bill introduced in
1961 would have required the Secretary of Health, Education and Welfare
(HEW) to consult with "recognized national listing or accrediting bodies" in
setting standards for hospitals, nursing homes, and home health agencies."'
This bill also permitted the Secretary to grant deemed status to these health
care providers: to the extent that the Secretary found national accreditation
bodies to provide reasonable assurances that conditions of participation would
be met, accredited hospitals, nursing homes, and home health agencies would
be deemed to meet quality conditions of Medicare participation.'" Both
161
Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 380.
'2
Id.
'" F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 148-50. The ANHA (now the American Health Care
Association) and AAHA lost their seats on the Commission when the Accreditation Council for
Long Term care was established in 1971,
Reorganization, supra
note 91, at 5.
15
*
F.
Hair,
supra
note 72, at 150-51.
155
P. CORNING, THE EVOLUTION OF MEDICARE FROM IDEA TO LAW 74.76 (1969);
Cohen & Ball,
Social Security Amendments of 1965: Summary and Legislative History,
SOC. SEC. BULL.,
Sept. 1965, at 3, 3-4.
166
H.R. 4700, introduced in 1959 would have permitted any licensed hospital to receive
Medicare funds. H.R. 4700, 86th Cong., 1st Sess. (d)(1) (1959),
reprinted in Hospital, Nursing
Home, and Surgical Benefits for.OASI BenefiCianes,
Hearings on H.R. 4700 before the House Comm.
on Ways and Means, 86th Cong., 1st Sess. 3 (1959).
'" H.R. 4222, 87th Cong., 1st Sess. 5 1607 (1961)
reprinted in Health Services for the Aged
Under the Social Security Insurance System Hearings before the House Comm. on Ways and Means,
86th
Cong., 1st Sess. 7 (1961).
158
Id. , 5
1608(b) at 7.8.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
853
HEWI
59
and AHA'
6
° supported reliance on JCAH accreditation to assure
quality.
Proposed Medicare legislation introduced in subsequent years steadily
strengthened the position of the Joint Commission."' These changes were
warmly supported by the AHA. Kenneth Williamson, an Associate Director of
the AHA, testified in
1965:
We also believe that it is particularly important that the references to the
Joint Commission on the Accreditation of Hospitals .... be retained in the
bill as it provides that the Secretary cannot establish standards whose re-
quirements are in
excess
of those which the health field itself prescribes. This
understandably gives a great feeling of comfort to the health fteld.
162
The Medicare statute, as finally enacted, not only required HEW to accept
JCAH accreditation as a conclusive determination of
hospital quality for par-
ticipation
in the Medicare program, but forbid HEW to promulgate standards
of quality higher than those adopted by JCAH.'
63
The reasons for heavy reliance by Medicare on JCAH were twofold. First,
there was substantial political pressure to get the Medicare program fully oper-
ational rapidly.'" President Johnson, with a large political stake in Medicare,
"9
Id.
at 223 (statement of Abraham Ribicoff, Secretary of HEW July 24, 1961). Dur-
ing 1961 hearings, Secretary Ribicoff of HEW testified that if required to immediately imple-
ment Medicare, he would " ... hand down an order that any hospital that was accredited by the
Joint Commission on Accreditation would be prima facie eligible."
Id.
at 223. He further stated
"I would give the greatest respect, as I do now, to the Joint Commission on Hospital Accredita-
tion. I think they are doing a fine job in America to raise the standards of our hospitals, and I
would not look behind their accreditation."
Id.
at 224.
'
5
° In his testimony during the 1961 hearings, AMA president Frank Groner supported
the notion of permitting JCAH accredited hospitals to participate in Medicare.
Id.
at 250 (state-
ment of Dr. Frank S. Groner, President, AMA, July 26, 1961).
163
§
1806(a) of H.R. 11865, defined hospital as an institution which "meets such other
of the requirements prescribed for the accreditation of hospitals by the Joint Commission on the
Accreditation of Hospitals as the Secretary finds necessary in the interest of health and safety of
individuals who are furnished services by or in the institution." H.R. 11865, 5 1806(a) 88th
Cong., 2d Sess., (1964),
reprinted in Social Security, Medical Care for the Aged Amendments: Hearings
before the Senate Comm. on Finance,
80th Cong., 2d Sess. 21 (1964). The bill further provided that
"an institution shall be deemed to meet the conditions of participation under 5 1806(a) ... if
such institution is accredited as a hospital by the Joint Commission on the Accreditation of
Hospitals."
Id. 5
1808(b)(1) at 25. H.R. 6675 provided that hospital certification requirements
promulgated by the Secretary could not "be higher than the comparable requirements prescribed
for the accreditation of hospitals by the Joint Commission on the Accreditation of Hospitals."
H.R. 6675, 5 1861(c)(8), 89th Cong., 1st Sess. (1965),
reprinted in Social Security. Hearings before the
Senate Comm. on Finance,
89th Cong., 1st Sess., 21 (1965).
162
Medical Care for the Aged,
Executive Hearings before the House Committee on Ways
and Means, 89th Cong., 1st Sess., 2236 (1965) (Statement of Kenneth Williamson, Associate
Director AHA, Feb. 2, 1965).
163
See
Pub. L. No. 89-97, 5 1861(e)(8) (codified at 42 U.S.C. 1395x(e)(g) (Supp. II
1966); 5 1865 (codified at 42 U.S.C. 1395bb (Supp.
II
1966)) 79 Stat. 290, 315, 326, 327, 89th
Cong., 1st Sess. (1965). Insofar as .5 1861(e)(7) required hospitals to be licensed in states that had
licensing laws as an additional prerequisite to certification, it was possible that an accredited
hospital could be refused Medicare certification if a state denied it licensure.
164
J.
FEDER, MEDICARE: THE POLITICS OF FEDERAL HOSPITAL INSURANCE 11
854
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
believed that its success depended on maximum access from the beginning of
the program, and thus on immediate near universal hospital participation."'
Those who had to administer the program were greatly relieved to have a fully
developed quality certification system,'" that, by the mid-1960's; accredited
sixty percent of the hospitals, and eighty-seven percent of the hospital beds in
the country."' Second, reliance on the JCAH was strongly supported by the
AHA. Though the AMA had consistently and vigorously opposed Medi-
care,
168
the AHA had cautiously supported parts of the Medicare program'"
and the use of JCAH for hospital regulation strengthened this support.
Following the passage of the Medicare law in 1965, JCAH entered a
period of rapid growth and elaboration. In 1966 it had about a dozen staff, a
dozen surveyors and a budget of about $500,000 annually; by the late 1970's it
had about 350 employees, 100 surveyors and an annual budget of $14
million.'" The JCAH also further diversified its efforts, entering into agree-
ments with twenty-four national organizations representing health constituen-
cies to establish four accreditation councils to accredit different kinds of med-
ical care."' While the councils were subject to the ultimate authority of the
Board of Commissioners, they functioned with substantial independence in set-
ting standards and in recommending accreditation decisions."' Finally, be-
tween 1966 and 1971 theiCAH completely rewrote its hospital accreditation
standards. The effect of this rewrite is disputed: JCAH claims it created a
higher national minimum hospital quality care standard;'
73
others claim that
the new standards were more vague and less demanding than the earlier stand-
ards."
4
(1977).
165
Id.; J.
FEDER, THE SOCIAL SECURITY ADMINISTRATION AND MEDICARE: A
STRATEGY FOR IMPLEMENTATION IN TOWARD A NATIONAL HEALTH POLICY 19,
22-23 (K.
Friedman & S. Rakoff eds.
1977).
166
See supra
note
159,
telephone interview with Wilbur Cohen, Aug. 30, 1982.
165
J.
FEDER,
supra
note 164, at
9;
Cashman and Myers,
Medicare: Standards of Service
in
a
New Program — Licensure, Certification, and Accreditation,
57
AM.
J.
OF PUB. HEALTH
1107, 1114
(1967).
166
See generally
R.
HARRIS, A SACRED TRUST
(1966) (describing the AMA lobbying
campaign against Medicare).
ISO See
P.
CORNING,
supra
note 155, at
79, 80;
Telephone interview with Wilbur Cohen,
(Aug. 30,
1982).
Ste also
H.
SOMERS & A. SOMERS, MEDICARE AND THE HOSPITALS 83
n. l0
(1967).
17
° Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 8.
Affeldt, supra note 53, at 186.
172
See JCAH Plans Reorganization,
PERSPECTIVES ON ACCREDITATION,
Sept.-Oct.
1978
at
6.
The Accreditation Council for Services for the Mentally Retarded and Other Developmen-
tally Disabled Persons was established in
1969;
the Accreditation Council for Psychiatric
Facilities in 1970, the Accreditation Council for Long-Term Care Facilities in 1971, and the Ac-
creditation Council for Ambulatory Health Care in
1975,
Reorganization, supra
note 93, at 5.
17
' Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 8; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 381.
176
S. LAw &
S. POLAN, PAIN
AND PROFIT, 65-67 (1978);
A. SOMERS,
supra
note
127,
at
130, 131. The revised standards included a standard for review of hospital utilization by patients
parallel to that found in the Medicare law. H.
SOMERS & A. SOMERS,
supra
note 169, at 83.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
855
This period of growth and elaboration was not without its trials. In the
early 1970's, growing consumer awareness led to controversy about the JCAH
role in the Medicare program. In mid-1970, the National Welfare Rights Or-
ganization and a number of other consumer groups met with the JCAH,
1
"
presenting JCAH with twenty-five demands for opening up the accreditation
process and for altered standards to require of hospitals more consumer partici-
pation and greater responsibility toward the poor.
16
Almost simultaneously
several consumer groups sued HEW, challenging the delegation of authority
for Medicare certification to the JCAH as a delegation of public authority to a
private body in violation of the United States Constitution.'" The case was
precipitated by JCAH accreditation of the San Francisco General Hospital and
the District of Columbia General Hospital despite serious problems and con-
sumer complaints.
18
Also in 1970 and 1971 a number of legislative proposals,
including a bill introduced by Senator Edward Kennedy to establish an in-
dependent federal commission for accreditation, further challenged the role of
the JCAH.'
79
JCAH responded to this consumer pressure by adding a preamble to its
standards recognizing patient's rights, and incorporating public information
interviews into the accreditation process.'" It briefly had a consumer advisory
committee. The leadership of JCAH, however, continued to identify JCAH as
a consultant accountable to the medical care industry and to reject the role of a
regulator accountable to the public.
18
'
JCAH standards and enforcement also had become a source of concern to
those administering the Medicare program. The annual report on Medicare of
the Health Insurance Benefits Advisory Council (HIBAC), issued July 1969
and covering July 1, 1966 through December 31, 1967, stated that the Council
"found reason for concern that JCAH standards are not applied with the fre-
quency of inspection and range of inspector skills necessary to assure a high
degree of effectiveness" and that "the JCAH standards in some cases impose
an undesirably low ceiling" on Medicare health and safety standards.'"
1
" Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 382, 383.
16
Other demands are set forth in Worthington & Silver,
Regulation of Quality of Care in
Hospitals: The Need for Change,
35 LAIN & CONTEMP. PROBS., 305, 328-31 (1970).
'" Self-Help for the Elderly v. Richardson, No. 2016-71 (D.D.C. 1972).
See infra
text
accompanying notes 571-616 discussing the delegation doctrine.
18
Hearings, supra
note 54, at 1944-71 (testimony of Fred Hiestand, attorney for plain-
tiffs), 1976-89 (testimony of Kenneth Barres and Bruce Terris); J. FEDER,
supra
note 164, at 23,
Suit Challenges Delegation of Medical Standards toJCAH, 7
HOSP. FRAC., Feb. 1972, at 186, 187, 195,
196, 199 (1972) (hereinafter cited as Suit
Challenges); Suit Calls JCAH Role in Medicare Unconstitu-
tional,
12
MED. WORLD NEWS,
Nov. 5, 1971, at 18 (hereinafter cited as Suit
Calls).
"
9
S. 3327, 92d Cong., 2d Sess., (1972) reprinted in 118 Cong. Rec. 31551,
31557-31561; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 382.
'
8
° Porterfield,
The JCAH: A Look at What Has Changed, What Has Endured,
5 HOSP.
MED, STAFF,
Sept. 9766 at 23, 25; Schlicke,
JCAH and the Federal Government,
64 BULL. AM.
COLL. SURG., March 1979, 23, 24, 25; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 382,
18
' Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 8-9, 11, 12;
Suit Calls, supra
note 178, at 19.
182
HEALTH INSURANCE BENEFITS ADVISORY COUNCIL (HIBAC) REPORT COVERING
856
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol.
24:835
HIBAC recommended that HEW be given authority to set standards for hospi-
tals and that states be given authority to inspect accredited facilities.
/83
Similar-
ly, several state agencies also began to criticize JCAH standards and inspec-
tions.
184
Congress responded to consumer and HIBAC concerns through the Social
Security Amendments of 1972, which permitted HEW to promulgate hospital
standards exceeding JCAH accreditation standards;
185
to validate JCAH ac-
creditation by state inspections performed randomly and in response to
substantial complaints;
186
and to decertify accredited hospitals that failed to
comply with the federal regulations."' The amendments relieved consumer
pressure on JCAH but increased tension between JCAH and HEW. The first
HEW report to Congress concerning the results of the validation surveys sub-
mitted in 1976 identified wide discrepancies between JCAH and state surveys,
with JCAH finding fewer deficiencies.'" JCAH responded publicly to this
report, pointing out that most of the additional deficiencies were in the physical
plant or fire safety areas, which it regarded as less directly related to the quality
of care.'" JCAH also improved its fire safety standards and inspection.'
90
HEW and the JCAH also clashed over the confidentiality of hospital ac-
creditation reports. The 1972 amendments required hospitals, as a condition of
Medicare participation, to release JCAH accreditation survey reports to HEW
for validation of accreditation.'
9
' Although the statute specified that the reports
were to be kept confidential, HEW in 1975 released a number of JCAH defi-
ciency letters to a consumer organization pursuant to a Freedom of Informa-
tion Act request.
'
92
JCAH immediately ceased providing validation reports to
THE PERIOD
JULY
1,
1966 - DECEMBER 31, 1967, 11 (1969).
'"
Id.
at 11, 12.
194
HIBAC,
Task Force on Extended Care Services,
SELECTED STATE REPORTS, staff report,
at 5, Ark. Report at 5, 6. Fla. Report at 9, 10 (Sept. 4, 1968).
'" Pub. L, No. 92-603 5 244(b)(1), 86 Stat. 1329, 1423 (1972) (codified at 42 U.S.C.
1395bb(a)(4) (1976)).
See
SEN. REP. No. 92-1230 92d Cong., 2d Sess. 290 (1972) for the
legislative history.
'" Pub. Law No. 92-603 5 244(a), 86 Stat. 1329, 1422, 1423 (1972) (codified at 42
U.S.C.
$
1395aa(c) (1976)).
197 Pub. Law No. 92-603 5 244(b)(2), 86 Stat. 1329, 1423 (1972) (codified at 42 U.S.C.
5 1395bb(b) (1976)).
198
HEW, REPORT OF MEDICARE VALIDATION SURVEYS OF HOSPITALS ACCREDITED
BY THE JOINT COMMISSION ON THE ACCREDITATION OF HOSPITALS
5-7 (1975). Annual reports
on the results of validation surveys were required by Pub. Law No. 92-603, 5 244d, 86 Stat.
1329, 1423 (1972) (codified at 42 U.S.C. $ 1395bb (1976)).
189
JCAH REPORT TO CONGRESS
I
MB (1975).
199
Lewis,
The Uncertain Future of JCAH, 4
MOD. HEALTH CARE, August 1975, 21-22;
Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 9, 10; Schlicke,
supra
note 185, at 26.
See also
Affeldt,
JCAH the Best
Game in Town,
59 HOSP. PROG. September 1978, 51, 53 (explaining differences in HEW and
JCAH survey procedures that resulted in discrepancies in survey results).
'
91
Pub. Law No. 92-603, 5 244(b)(1) 86 Stat. 1329, 1423 (1972) (codified at 42 U.S.C.
5 1395bb(a)(2) (1976)).
192
Schlicke,
supra note 51, at 9; Van Amringe,
Putting Hospital Standards on the Examining
Table,
HCFA FORUM, December 1980, at 23;
Hospital Accreditation - Where Do We Go From Here,
2 HEALTH PERSPECTIVES Mar.-Apr. 1975, at 4, (hereinafter cited as Hospital Accreditation).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
857
HEW and sued to enjoin any further releases.'" In October of 1975, JCAH
and HEW reached a settlement barring release by HEW of accreditation let-
ters or accompanying recommendations or comments.
194
Finally, the emergence of Professional Standards Review Organizations
(PSRO's)t" in 1972 challenged JCAH dominance of hospital regulation.'"
The PSRO legislation established a quality and utilization peer review pro-
gram for Medicare and Medicaid financed hospital care wholly independent of
JCAH. The program even duplicated some of JCAH's quality audit pro-
cedures.
191
A final notable development in the early 1970's was the increased em-
phasis of JCAH on evaluation of quality of patient care. JCAH had long been
accused of emphasizing physical and administrative structures - the capacity
to deliver care, rather than the actual quality of patient care."' In response to
this criticism (and perhaps to other factors)''' JCAH began to require outcome
oriented hospital quality review programs. It also developed a specific system,
the Performance Evaluation Procedure for Auditing and Improving Patient
Care (PEP),
2
" that hospitals could use to meet this standard.
4. Recent Developments - 1975 to the Present
During 1977 and 1978, JCAH was extensively reorganized. The accredita-
tion councils, set up in the mid-1960's, had functioned with increasing
autonomy, creating administrative and managerial problems and, some claim,
threatening the control of JCAH's member groups over the accreditation pro-
gram."' Accreditation staff functioned under a dual authority, responding
both to the accreditation councils and to JCAH management.
202
To eliminate
these accountability problems, JCAH abolished the accreditation councils and
established the current PTAC system described earlier."' Two of the four ac-
I" Joint Commission on Accreditation of Hospitals v. Weinberger, No. 75 C175 (N. D.
Ill. Oct. 8, 1975) (dismissed by stipulation).
19*
Id.
19
'
Pub. Law No. 92-603, § 249F, 86 Stat. 1329, 1429-1445, (1972) (codified at 42
U.S.C. § 1320c-1320c19 (1976)).
196
Ellis,
supra
note 54, at 36; Porterfield,
supra
note 180, at 23, 24; Schlicke,
supra
note
180, at 26, 27.
'" Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 10, 11;
see
Crosby,
supra
note 54, at 133, 134.
'" Crosby,
supra
note 54, at 133.
'" For an analysis which attributes the development of JCAH quality review to the
malpractice crisis, see S.
LAW &
S. POLAN,
supra note 174, at 65-67 (1976).
200
Id. See
C.
JACOBS,
T. CHRISTOFFEL & N. DIXON, MEASURING THE
QUALITY
OF
PATIENT CARE: THE RATIONALE FOR OUTCOME AUDIT,
ix-x
(1976).
See also
Crosby,
supra
note
54, at 134; Porterfield,
A Farewell Look at JCAH Standard Audit Requirements,
6
-
HOSP. MED. STAFF,
July 1977, at 29, 31; Porterfield,
JCAH Board Adopts Schedule for Implementation of Quality Review, 3
HOSP. MED. STAFF, Sept. 1974, at 33 (discussing the PEP).
201
Crosby,
supra
note 54, at 136, 137;
JCAH Moves to Change its Policy Structures,
7 AHCA
WEEKLY NOTES, Oct. 6, 1978, at 3 (hereinafter
JCAHMoves); Reorganization, supra
note 91, at 5;
JCAH Plans Reorganization, supra
note 172, at 6.
202
JCAH Moves, supra
note
201, at 3.
202
See supra notes 44-47 and accompanying text.
858
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
creditation councils refused to go along with the reorganization proposal: three
of the five members of the Ambulatory Health Care Council broke off to
establish an independent Accreditation Association for Ambulatory Health
Care;
204
eight of the eleven members of the Mental Retardation and De-
velopmental Disabilities Council also rejected the arrangement and set up an
independent accreditation body.
206
JCAH continued its own ambulatory facili-
ty accreditation program under a PTAC, but has largely abandoned the men-
tal retardation/developmental disabilities facility program.
2
°
6
The late 1970's and early 1980's also marked a rapproachment between
JCAH and HEW. A 1979 GAO Repoit essentially supported a continued
JCAH role in Medicare certification.
207
Increasingly, HEW sought to
cooperate with rather than to police JCAH:
2
" new 'HEW validation regula-
tions issued in 1980 emphasized reconciling discrepancies between JCAH and
state inspection reports more than monitoring JCAH performance.
209
JCAH
overtures included attempts to coordinate activities with the PSRO's.
21
° In May
of 1981, the Reagan Administration, as part of its regulatory reform efforts,
proposed permitting JCAH to certify nursing homes for participation in
Medicare and Medicaid.
2
tt
The late seventies also saw an increase in state
reliance on JCAH for licensure. 1979 and 1980 GAO Reports recommended
that HEW encourage coordination between the JCAH accreditation and state
licensure programs.
212
As of 1982, thirty-eight states relied on JCAH standard-
ization or accreditation in some way in their medical regulation programs.
213
At the same time as the government increasingly has been relying on
JCAH as part of a program of deregulation, JCAH, ironically, has undertaken
deregulation efforts of its own. The 1970 standards are currently being sub-
stantially revised to make them simpler and more flexible.
2
'
4
In particular, the
264
Crosby,
supra
note 54, at 137.
205
206
Id. , AP-MRDD Discontinued in Present Form,
JCAH
PERSPECTIVES ON ACCREDITA-
TION,
July-Aug. 1979, at 2.
205
GAO
REPORT
B-164031(4),
THE MEDICARE HOSPITAL CERTIFICATION
SYSTEM
NEEDS REFORM,
ii, 14, 16, 19, 31 (1979); Schlicke,
supra
note 185, at 27-28;
GAO Report Favors
JCAH,
PERSPECTIVES ON ACCREDITATION,
July-Aug. 1979, at 1.
208
See, e.g.,
Derzon,
Needed.• A Durable JCAH-HCFA Partnership,
59
Host'. PROGRESS,
Sept. 1978, at 54; Schlicke,
supra
note 180, at 25-27; Van Amrige,
supra
note 192, at 23-25.
2"
45 Fed. Reg. 74826 (1980) (codified at 42 C.F.R. $S 405.1901, 405.1902 (1981)).
210 C
n
S. B
LUM, P.
GERTMAN & J. RABINOW,
PSRO's
AND THE LAW,
78-79 (1977);
Schlicke, supra note 51, at 10-11; Van Amrige,
supra
note 192, at 24.
211
See supra
text accompanying and authority cited in notes 63, 64.
212
GAO Report B-199186,
INFORMATION ON HOSPITAL INSPECTIONS, REPORTING
REQUIREMENTS AND LIFE SAFETY CODE ENFORCEMENT
3-5 (1980) (hereinafter cited as 1980
GAO
REPORT);
GAO Report,
supra
note 207, at 34; Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 11.
213
See supra
text accompanying and authority cited in notes 65-71.
214
Affeldt,
New Directions in Standards and Survey Process,
10 HOSP. MED. STAFF,
Aug.
1981, at 24; Laviolette,
JCAH Board Mulls Radical Survey Change,
11 MED. HEALTH CARE,
June
1981, at 18-19; Laviolette,
Simpler JCAH Standards on Thawing Board, 11
MED.
HEALTH CARE,
Feb. 1981, at 33, 34; Laviolette,
JCAH Will Go Easy on QA Standards Surveys,
10 MED. HEALTH
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
859
quality assurance standard has been revised to eliminate specific numerical
audit requirements and give hospitals substantial flexibility in achieving com-
pliance."' JCAH has also moved from a two to three year accreditation cycle
and toward more reliance on self-conducted surveys by hospitals.
216
Finally, JCAH, which has spent relatively little time in court during its 31
year history, has recently become the defendant in an increasing number of law
suits that reflect varying aspects of JCAH's significant role as a private and
public regulator. Several antitrust cases have been brought, pressing claims
that JCAH and its constituent members and hospitals have conspired to ex-
clude chiropractors, psychologists and other non-physician health care practi-
tioners from access to hospitals.'" Psychiatric hospital patients who lost their
eligibility for Supplemental Social Security payments when the hospital lost its
Medicaid certification because of JCAH disaccreditation, have challenged the
delegation of authority to JCAH to certify health care facilities for federal pro-
grams."' The suit claims alternatively that JCAH decertification decisions are
acts of the federal government, requiring due process. Moreover, a number of
malpractice cases brought against hospitals have included the JCAH as a de-
fendant, claiming that JCAH accreditation should serve as a guarantee of
quality.
219
In summary, JCAH is a private entity governed by representatives of
hospitals and physicians. Its most important function is the accreditation of
hospitals, but JCAH also accredits a variety of other health care providers. In
theory, JCAH accreditation is voluntary. In practice, most acute care hospitals
are JCAH accredited because of the important role of accreditation in private
or public licensing, certification, and financing programs. Despite JCAH's
CARE, Nov. 1980, at 11-12;
Board Considers Major Changes,
JCAH PERSPECTIVES, July-Aug.
1981, at
1; JCAH Treads Lightly on Survey of QA Standard,
11 MED. HEALTH CARE, June 1981, at
46. One particular move towards deregulation is a weakening of requirements for informed con-
sent documentation, Affeldt,
Patients Rights,
11 HOSP. MED. STAFF, Feb. 1982 at 9, 10-11.
215
QA Standard Approved,
PERSPECTIVES ON ACCREDITATION, May-June 1979, at 1.
216
Board Sets Guidelines for Three Year Accreditation, JCAH
PERSPECTIVES, Jan.-Feb. 1982,
at 1;
JCAH Board Approves Three-Year Accreditation,
JCAH PERSPECTIVES, Sept.-Oct. 1981, at 1.
217
v. JCAH, 354 F.2d 515 (D.C. Cir. 1965); Wilk v. AMA, 635 F.2d 1295 (7th
Cir. 1980) (appeal pending No. 81-1331 7th Cir. argued 1981); Garland v. Soc'y of
Anesthesiologists No. 81-4278 (N.D. Cal. Second amended complaint filed May 10, 1982);
Health Care Equalization Comm. of the Iowa Chiropractic Society v. Iowa Medical Soc'y, 501
F. Supp. 970 (S.D. Iowa 1980) pending No. 79-381-A; New York v. AMA, No. 79C 1732
(E.D.N.Y. dismissed July 9, 1981); Ohio v. JCAH, Civ. No. C-2-79-1158 (filed Dec. 14, 1979);
Slavek v. AMA, 1982-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) 1 64,509 (E.D. Pa. Jan. 27, 1982).
See also
In re
Chiropractic Antitrust Litigation, 483 F. Supp. 811 (J.P.M.D.L. 1980) (deciding issues in same
litigation not directly related to those considered here).
2
"
Cospito v. Califano, No. 77-869 (D.N.J. 1983) (granting and denying several cross-
motions for partial summary judgment); 80 F.R.D. 374 (1981).
219
Green v. Carlson, 581 F.2d 669 (7th Cir. 1978) of 'd,446 U.S. 14 (1980); Ruggirello
v. Memorial Hospital, No. 79-314-C7 (Cir. Ct. Macomb County Mich.); Kele v. United States,
No. C79-1093A (N.D. Ga.); Blanchard v. Our Lady of the Lake Medical Center, No. 231,311
(19th Judicial Dist. East Baton Rouge, La.); State of La. v. JCAH, No. 82-938 (4th Dist.
Quachita, La. filed March 18, 1982).
860
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
continued identification as a private consultant to the medical industry, JCAH
plays a major and sometimes controversial role in government regulatory pro-
grams. The Medicare program, in particular, relies heavily on JCAH ac-
creditation for certifying facilities for participation in Medicare. Through its
standards and its accreditation program, JCAH has the primary responsibility
for the quality of care provided in American hospitals.
II. A MODEL FOR UNDERSTANDING THE
JOINT COMMISSION
A.
Standardization
Standardization and certification are not, of course, unique to hospital
care.
22
° During the first three decades of the twentieth century the idea of
achieving efficiency through voluntary standardization swept the country,
bringing about the standardization of characteristics of many industrial prod-
ucts,
22
' including the viscosity of oil, sizes of lumber, and composition of steel
alloys."' While the role of, and reasons for, standardization in medical care
have received little study, the phenomenon of industrial standardization, par-
ticularly the economics of standardization, has been the subject of extensive in-
quiry."' This literature contributes much to an understanding of the hospital
standardization effort. This article will, therefore, discuss at some length the
economics of standardization, as it has generally come to be understood, and
apply this learning to understanding the JCAH.
Industrial standards fall into two basic categories: standards for uni-
formity and standards for quality.
224
Uniformity standards can further be
broken down into standards primarily adopted to promote interchangeability
of products (usually of parts such as nuts and bolts) or standards primarily
adopted to promote economies of scale either by making possible large scale
production or by simplifying market exchanges (such as standard bond paper
or lumber sizes).
225
Although this is not their primary purpose, JCAH hospital standards can
be understood as uniformity standards. They help to make the product,
"hospital care," or component parts of this product, such as radiology and
220
Standardization of medical care itself was not limited
to hospitals. The AMA as-
sumed the task of standardizing medical education by founding its Council on Medical Educa-
tion in 1904 and went on to achieve rapid and dramatic results following the release of the Flex-
ner Report in 1910. The ACS undertook not only to standardize hospital care but also the prac-
tice of surgery.
See
L. DAVIS,
supra
note 90, at 33,
61; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 58-73, 87,
221
D.
HEMENWAY, INDUSTRYWIDE VOLUNTARY PRODUCT STANDARDS, 13-16, 22-24
(1975); NATIONAL BUREAU OF STANDARDS, REPORT OF THE VOLUNTARY STANDARDIZATION
POLICY STUDY GROUP 2-3
(1970); Hamilton,
The Role of Non-Governmental Standards in the Develop-
ment of Mandatory Federal Standards Affecting Safety or Health,
56 TEX. L. REV.
1329, 1368-70 (1978).
222
D.
HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at
15, 16, 24,
223
See
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, STANDARDS AND CERTIFICATION (1978); P.
HARTER, REGULATORY USE OF STANDARDS
(1979) and authorities cited
supra,
at note 221.
224
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 8, 9, 19, 45.
222
Id.
at 19.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
861
pathology, more uniform, and thus promote interchangeability of radiologists
and pathologists between hospitals and, perhaps, simplify comparisons of
hospitals by those who consume their services. JCAH standards are, however,
more commonly and accurately understood as qualiiy standards. To under-
stand quality standards it is necessary to consider the economics of informa-
tion,
B.
Economics of Information
Quality standards are a form of information. A major function they serve
is to facilitate the smooth operation of markets for goods and services. For a
competitive market to exist, participants in the market must have the means of
acquiring information regarding exchange opportunities and the prices of
available goods and services in the market.
226
Traditional price theory assumes
that this information is costless and universally available.
227
Price and quality
information is, of course, seldom universally available and is often costly. Con-
sumers, however, have economic incentives to try to seek out or create infor-
mation, as informed choices are more efficient and can lead to an increase,
potentially significant, in the real utility of income.
228
Consumers may obtain
information about goods and services in a variety of ways: from their own ef-
forts, from sellers, or from independent sources.
First, consumers may produce information themselves through inspection
(search) or experience.
229
Consumers may themselves inspect simple goods, or
search advertisements or literature concerning products to make informed
decisions."° Consumers also get information through experience by purchas-
ing a product and evaluating the utility obtained from it
2
" or relying upon the
experience of others with the product.
232
Experience is most useful for
evaluating frequently purchased goods, as to which extensive experience can
be rapidly acquired.
233
Consumer inspection and experience are, however, of limited value for
purchasing hospital services.
234
First, the complex, technological nature of
226
Id.
at 47; J. GELMAN, COMPETITION AND HEALTH PLANNING: AN ISSUES PAPER,
38 (1982).
227
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 47.
226
GELMAN,
supra
note 226, at 40-42; Beales, Croswell & Salop,
The Efficient Regula-
tion of Consumer Information,
24 J. LAW AND ECON., 491, 501-02 (1981).
229
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 51; Nelson,
Information and Consumer Behavior,
78 J.
Or
POL. ECON., 311, 311-12 (1970).
239
J.
GELMAN,
supra
note 226, at 40.
231
D.
HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 51-52; Hirschliefer,
Where Are We in the Theory of
Information,
85 PROC. AM. ECON. ACAD. 31, 37-38 (1972); Nelson,
supra
note 229, at 312.
232 Nelson,
supra
note 229, at 321-23.
233
supra
note 231, at 37-38; Nelson,
supra
note 229, at 314.
234
CI J.
GELMAN,
supra
note 226, at 39, 40 (discussing consumer use of search and ex-
perience in medical care purchases). For a more sanguine view of the ability of consumers to
make medical care purchases,
see
Frech,
The Long Lost Market in Health Care
in NEW APPROACH,
supra
note
1, at 44, 47-50. Frech argues that consumers are more knowledgeable concerning their
862
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
hospital care makes direct inspection by consumers impractical. Second, the
emergent nature of many hospitalization decisions limits the time available for
evaluating alternative hospitals. Moreover, inpatient hospitalization is a suffi-
ciently infrequent experience that consumers will find experience of limited use
in evaluating quality. While the experience of others may occasionally be of
some use, the wide variety of medical conditions makes this experience unreli-
able. Finally, consumers are handicapped in assessing the product of hospital
care, as it is distinguished from most other products by "credence"
qualities:
2
" not only is the consumer ill-equipped to evaluate hospital care by
search before purchase, but also to understand and evaluate experience after-
wards. The consumer must trust professionals not only as to diagnosis and
treatment, but also for interpretation of treatment results.
Sellers are a second source of quality information for consumers. A seller
may have particular incentives to produce information if it tends to differen-
tiate advantageously the seller's product from other products on the market,
and thus allows the seller to recover the cost of information production and dis-
semination through increased sales.
2
" Individual sellers disseminate informa-
tion through a variety of means, including advertising, brand name promo-
tion, or guarantees. Advertising assists consumer investigation by providing
accessible product information; brand names facilitate consumer use of experi-
ence by allowing easy identification of products with which the consumer has
previously had a good (or bad) experience; guarantees permit the seller to ap-
pear to alter his pay-off matrix so that superior product quality appears to be a
rational goal for the seller to pursue.
237
These means may also serve as signals
of other quality characteristics not otherwise readily discernable.
238
While con-
sumers may find seller produced information useful, there are risks in con-
sumers relying exclusively on such information. Information produced by
discrete sellers may be unreliable and one-sided. In particular, sellers may tend
to emphasize marginally important attributes which differentiate their prod-
ucts from others in a particular market.
239
Again, this traditional source of consumer information is not well-suited
to the medical care context. Dissemination of medical care quality information
to ultimate consumers by sellers has been relatively rare.
240
Advertising aimed
own value schedules than are providers, and thus are better equipped to make certain health care
choices.
3
"
For a discussion of "credence goods,"
see
Darby & Karni,
Free Competition and the Op-
timal Amount of Fraud,
16 J. LAW & ECON., 67, 68-72 (1973); Wolfson, Tribilcock & Tuohy,
Regulating The Professions: A Theoretical Framework
in S. ROTTERBERG, OCCUPATIONAL LICEN-
SURE AND REGULATION 180, 190-92 (1980).
23.9
Beales, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note 228, at 502.
4]7
D.
HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 52-53; Hirschliefer,
supra
note 231, at 37; Nelson,
Advertising ar Information,
82 J. POL ECON., 729 (1974).
239
Beales, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note 228, at 506-07.
339
Id.
at 506.
7
" Advertising aimed at intermediate producers of health care, on the other hand, is ex-
tensive and highly sophisticated, as a cursory examination of pharmaceutical advertisements in
July 19831
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
863
directly at consumers by professionals has until recently been regarded as
unethical, and guarantees may increase malpractice exposure.
2
" Moreover,
the complexity of a product such as hospital care renders advertising of limited
value.
242
Similarly, brand name identification may play a role in the competi-
tion of health care institutions — consider the Mayo or Menninger Clinics —
but the role is minor.
Third, information about products may be produced neither by con-
sumers nor sellers but independently as a separate commodity. Information is
a quite peculiar commodity. First, on the supply side, the economies of scale in
the production of information are significant: once information is produced it
can be disseminated at very low marginal cost.''' These economies of scale
should in theory lead to a natural production monopoly and discourage entry of
additional information sellers into the market.'" Such a monopoly may not be
profitable, however. Information is not subject to the same imperatives of scar-
city as are most other goods: its possession by one person does not exclude its
possession by others. Indeed, sharing of information may improve its quantity
and quality.
245
As buyers of information have no incentives not to resell it, or
even pass it on for free, sellers of information face substantial free rider prob-
lems. Finally, the initial cost of production of information about a complex
product (such as hospital care) may be very substantial, further discouraging
sellers from entering the market. These factors are serious impediments to the
production of information about products.
There are also significant problems with marketing information on the de-
mand side.
A
purchaser will often be unable to judge the value of information
until it is purchased, for if the seller of information allows the buyer to inspect
the information, it is effectively transferred before purchase.'" Moreover, even
after a buyer has purchased information, he can never be sure of its value,
because this value can only be evaluated by the use of additional information
which can only be obtained at additional cost."' These factors may discourage
demand for information and further impede its production.
any major medical journal will show.
241
It
is possible, however, that otherwise uninformative advertising could serve as a
signal of high quality care, see Hirschliefer, supra note 231, at 38; Nelson,
supra
note 237, at 745.
242
See
Comment,
A Prescription for Doctors.
-
Avoid Warranties,
28 LOY. L.J. 307 (1982),
Sullivan v. O'Connor, 363 Mass. 579, 296 N.E.2d 183 (1973).
242
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 47; Beales, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note 228, at
503-05.
244
Beaks, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note 228, at 503-05.
245
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 47; Beaks, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note 228, at
503-04.
246 D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 48. The seller may, however, convey some infor-
mation about information through signaling: one piece of information can be divulged that serves
as an adequate signal of the quality of undisclosed information.
247
Id.
at 48-49.
864
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
C.
Standardization and Certification: Contributions to Efficiency
Standardization and certification programs are common means of produc-
ing information as an independent commodity. By identifying for buyers rele-
vant aspects of product quality,
248
standards enable consumers to compare
rapidly and accurately the quality of a range of products, thus lowering search
costs and increasing efficiency.'" Standards identify more accurately than
advertising those product characteristics that are genuine signals of overall
product quality.
250
By focusing buyer-seller negotiations on a limited number
of relevant quality characteristics, standards lower exchange transaction costs,
focus competition on price, and lessen costly misunderstandings or disputes.'"
On the supply side, standards narrow product variation, permitting
economies of scale and accumulation of standardized inventory for rapid or
repeated delivery.
252
This in turn enhances buyer opportunities to evaluate
quality by experience. Standardization also facilitates producer entry into
markets by lowering research and development costs, decreasing brand
allegiance and increasing buyer acceptance.
253
Certification or grading programs further enhance the benefits of stand-
ardization, especially where complex products are involved.
254
While standards
identify important quality attributes, they do not inform the consumer which
products possess those attributes to what extent. If standards are complex or
application of standards requires technical expertise, standardization itself does
the consumer little good. An impartial certification program, however, can ap-
ply standards to evaluate products for the consumer, thus simplifying con-
sumer choices and assuring greater utility.'" Certification programs also
facilitate entry of products into a market by reducing the need for consumer
reliance on brand names or advertising.
256
D.
Efficiency Enhancing Motivations for Standardization and Certification Programs
Because of the problems in marketing information discussed earlier, it is
by no means certain that standardization or certification programs will emerge
2
" Id. at
55.
249
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, at 42, 43.
See also
Nelson,
supra
note
229, at 312-18 (discussing determinants affecting the optimal amount of consumer search).
2"
See
Beales, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note 228, at 506-07 on the limitations of advertis-
ing as a signal of product quality.
25
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, at 47-48; D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note
221, at 55.
25' D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 55,
see
Stigler,
The Economics of Information,
69 J.
POL. ECON. 213 (1961).
2s3
TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, at 45-46. Howe & Badger, An
Anti-
trust Challenge to Non-Profit Certifying Organizations: Conflicts of Interest and a Practical Rule of Reason Ap-
proach to Certification Programs as Industry-wide Builders of Competition and Efficiency,
60 WASH.
U.L.Q. 357, 376.78 (1982).
25
+ FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION, supra
note 223, at 86, 87.
255 Id.
206
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 60.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
865
in any particular market. Though consumers have much to gain from stand-
ardization and certification, it is unlikely that consumers will create standards
if the demand side of a market is large and diffuse."' The production of stand-
ards and the evaluation of sellers for a certification program is too costly a job
for any one consumer to undertake. Individual consumers, or groups of con-
sumers, theoretically could go into the business of creating standards for resale,
but the marketing problems discussed earlier, particularly the problem of free
riders, makes this a difficult undertaking. If consumers of a product are
unorganized and atomistic and the product itself is technical and complex, con-
sumer standardization and certification is particularly unlikely. Medical care is
such a product; not surprisingly, consumer standardization and certification of
medical care has been rare.
258
Nor is it surprising that JCAH, the major agent
of standardization and certification for institutional health care, is not spon-
sored by consumers.
Though sellers have some economic incentives to initiate standardization
or certification programs as discussed above, such programs will seldom be ad-
vantageous to any particular seller. Sellers of poor quality products will prefer
competition in a market characterized by minimal quality information, as they
have more to gain from purchase decisions based on random choice or strictly
on price. Sellers of high quality goods may well prefer product differentiation
based on brand name identification or advertising which may lift their goods
out of the competitive market.
259
Sellers may also oppose standardization
because it facilitates entry of new producers into the market. Standardization
by sellers is, therefore, not common,
26
° and it is understandable that the initial
push for hospital standardization did not come from the hospital industry; that
the ACS hospital standardization program existed for thirty-two years without
significant hospital input; and that even now the representatives of hospitals
make up less than a third of the JCAH Board."'
Under special conditions, however, either buyers or sellers may have
economic incentives to set up standardization and certification programs.
Buyers may do so if the demand side of a market is oligopsonistic or monop-
sonistic.
262
If any one buyer, or small group of easily organized buyers, con-
257 See
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 63-68.
258
It might be possible for consumers to accumulate the resources to carry on evaluation
of some health care services provided in highly concentrated urban markets or of health related
goods and services sold in a national market.
See
CONSUMER HEALTH PERSPECTIVES published
by the Consumer Commission on the Accreditation of Health Services, Inc., a New York-based
non-profit organization with union and consumer support, or publications of the Public Citizen
Health Research Groups, a Ralph Nader affiliate, which focus largely on pharmaceutical and
medical devices.
259
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 68.
260
Id
.
'61
See supra
text accompanying notes 34, 97-122, 130-47.
2
" D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 63-68. (If a market is controlled by one buyer it is
monopsonistic; if controlled by a few buyers, it is oligopsonistic).
866
BOSTON COLLEGE LA W REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
trols such a large share of a market that it can internalize enough of the benefits
of standardization and certification to outweigh the costs of the program,
standardization or certification is likely.'"
This form of concentration is likely if products are produced in vertical
chains of production, with highly concentrated intermediate producers, or if
products produced in one industry (complementary products) are necessary
complements to products produced in a coordinated, highly concentrated in-
dustry (primary products). Certification and standardization are common
wherever vertical or complementary production is found,'" For example, the
Society of Automotive Engineers (SAE), composed of employees and represen-
tatives of the auto companies, standardized component parts of autos such as
steel tubing or lock washers, and complementary products such as oil.'"
Standardization and certification of complementary products by pro-
ducers of a primary product increases demand for the primary and com-
plementary product, considered as a unit, by reducing the cost and, perhaps,
improving the quality of the complementary product."' The cost of the com-
plementary product is lowered because of reduced information costs and
economies of scale induced by coordinated demand.
267
Improved quality of the
complement may improve the utility of the primary product and protect it from
malfunctioning, thus preserving the reputation of and demand for the primary
product.'" Intermediate producers in vertical production chains standardize
products higher up the chain (initial products) to lower their costs and improve
the quality of inputs into their product (final products), thus increasing the
ultimate quality and utility of and demand for the final products.'"
The initial push for hospital standardization and certification came from a
group of surgeons, the ACS."° Surgeons are, in effect, intermediate producers
in the hospital production chain. Laboratory tests, medical records, and
x-rays, for example, are consumed not by patients but by physicians and
surgeons, who in turn deliver the products of diagnosis and treatment to the
patient."' Other aspects of hospital care, such as the hospital rooms, hospital
265
A classic example of standardization involving a single buyer is the prominent
role General Motors played in the standardization of steel alloys.
Id.
at 15.
264
Id.
at 74-75.
265
Id.
at 13-18. In addition the National Petroleum Institute has written standards not
for petroleum products, but for products purchased by petroleum companies such as steel plug
valves.
Id.
at 66. Similarly, the American Gas Association writes standards for gas appliances
and accessories which are complementary to their product.
Id.
at 75, 82.
266
Id.
at 75.
267
266
Id.
269
Id.
at 75-76.
2
"
See supra
text accompanying notes 97-111.
2
" M. FELDSTEIN, HEALTH CARE ECONOMICS 392 (1979); M. FELDSTEIN, HEALTH
ASSOCIATIONS AND THE DEMAND FOR LEGISLATION: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF HEALTH
44-46 (1977) (hereinafter FELDSTEIN, ASSOCIATIONS); J. Harris,
The Internal Organization of
Hospitals: Some Economic Implications,
8 BELL J. ECON.,
at
467-470 (1977);
See,
Redisch,
Physician
Involvement in Hospital Decision Making
in Zubkoff, Raskin & Hanft,
supra
note 1, 217 at 222-223.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
867
social work, and some nursing services complement the services of surgical
care, making the entire product of hospitalization of more or less utility to the
patient. Though the supply side of the market for surgeons is not as highly con-
centrated or organized as is the auto industry, the small size of the market in
the early twentieth century and the unity created by professional identity made
organization of the market relatively easy. Moreover, the market for surgery is
highly concentrated in any particular geographic and specialty market.
272
Surgeons had much to gain from hospital standardization. Standardi-
zation and certification helped to make surgery in the hospital a safe and attrac-
tive alternative to home surgery, thus making the work of surgeons more effi-
cient and effective, and permitting radical increases in demand for surgery and
the productivity of surgeons.
273
Control over hospital standardization also, in-
cidentally, assured physicians a central, indeed controlling, position in
hospitals.
274
To the extent that JCAH standardization and certification programs are
attributable to physicians and surgeons acting as intermediate producers,
JCAH may increase the utility of hospital services for ultimate consumers. A
primary economic goal of physicians and surgeons, as producers in a vertical
line of production and as sellers of services complementary to hospital care,
should be to increase patient satisfaction and thus to increase demand for their
services."' Though the relative inelasticity of demand for the services of physi-
cians and surgeons attributable to the necessity of those services may weaken
the influence of this goal, it still remains a significant determinant of physician
behavior. This goal of patient satisfaction is, moreover, also consistent with the
professional self-image of surgeons and physicians. It is to be expected,
therefore, that physicians within JCAH would push for standards and ac-
creditation decisions that would assure production by hospitals of high quality
inputs and complements to their services, to the benefit of patients.
Physician and surgeon dominance of hospital standardization, which no
doubt results from the relationship between physician and hospital services, has
a second, incidental, efficiency enhancing effect. Because JCAH is currently
responsive to a broad constituency of physicians, a major effect of JCAH at the
272
See
discussions of market for surgery in Marrese v. American Academy of Or-
thopaedic Surgeon, 692 F.2d 1083, 1095 (7th Cir. 1982) and in Robinson v. Magovern, 521 F.
Supp. 842, 877-86 (W.D. Pa. 1981).
223
H. SOMERS & A. SOMERS, DOCTORS, PATIENTS, AND HEALTH INSURANCE 41-42,
56, 57 (1962); Redisch,
supra
note 271, at 223.
274
Ste
generally, Saltman & Young,
The Hospital Power Equilibrium,
6 J. HEALTH POL.
POLY & L. 391 (1982).
275
See
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 75, 76. The pervasive effects of third party
payments on the medical care delivery system has been discussed exhaustively elsewhere and is
beyond the scope of this paper. It should be noted, however, that one effect of third party pay-
ment is undoubtedly to diminish consumer consciousness of the price of medical care, and thus to
increase the need for physicians to attend to consumer satisfaction and utility as arenas for com-
petition.
868
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
local hospital level is probably to increase the access of physicians to hospitals
through JCAH requirements of reasonable and fair procedures for determining
physician eligibility for staff privileges.
276
Just as producers of complementary or intermediate goods and services —
here physicians and surgeons — may have economic incentives for standardi-
zation and certification of product quality, so too may sellers — here hospitals.
The economic incentives of sellers will likely outweigh the disincentives
discussed above when the external costs placed on sellers of high quality prod-
ucts by sellers of low quality products exceed the costs of standardization. This
phenomenon was described by Ackerlof in his classic article on the market for
lemons.
27
If buyers are cognizant of the average quality of a product, but not
the quality of any particular individual product, buyers will be unwilling to pay
premium prices for allegedly superior products the quality of which they are
unable to assess. Thus sellers of above average products will be forced to sell
their products at a loss, and will either be driven out of the market or reduce
product quality. As sellers of high quality products leave the market, the
average quality in the market will continually decline. This will in turn
decrease demand and harm all sellers. In this situation, product standardi-
zation and certification will increase consumer confidence in the average prod-
uct by increasing the quality of that product.
278
This will increase demand,
willingness to pay higher prices, and product quality.
279
While standardization under these circumstances should improve the
quality of products in the market ,
28
° the degree to which quality will improve is
uncertain. If demand for a product is relatively inelastic because the product is
a necessity for which there are few substitutes, sellers may not be able to cause
any substantial increase in demand by raising the quality of the average prod-
uct above a very minimal level."' Further, if a product is sufficiently imper-
meable to consumer evaluation, standards emphasizing symbolic aspects of
276
A. SOUTHWICK, THE LAW
OF
HOSPITAL & HEALTH CARE ADMINISTRATION
456
(1978); Kissam, Webber, Bigns, & Holtzgraefe,
Antitrust and Hospital Privileges: Testing the Conven-
tional Wisdom,
70 CALIF. L. REV. 595, 648 (1982).
277 See
Akerlof,
The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism,
84 Q. J.
ECON. 488 (1970); D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 70-71; Weingast,
Physicians, DNA Research
Scientists, and the Market for Lemons,
in
REGULATING
THE
PROFESSIONS: A PUBLIC POLICY SYM-
POSIUM 81 (R. Blair & S. Rubin eds. 1980). This phenomenon is even more likely to occur in a
market in which sellers are unable to differentiate their product from other products through
advertising, brand market identification, or guarantees,
see
Beaks, Craswell & Salop,
supra
note
228, at 502.
2
"
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 70-71.
2"
One of the most dramatic examples of this effect of standards is the effect of Japanese
standards and inspection laws, enacted in 1949, which revolutionized the overall quality of prod-
ucts exported from Japan.
Id,
280
See
Gelman,
supra
note 226, at 134.
281
For example, an inner city public hospital can allow the quality of its care to fall to
very low levels before its clientele, dependent on its service by necessity, will cease to come to it
for help. It has little economic incentive to raise the quality of its care above that low level.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
869
quality may, in the short run at least, be as effective in increasing consumer de-
mand as standards emphasizing real quality.
262
As Compliance with such sym-
bolic standards may be much less expensive than compliance with standards
that accurately reflect quality, sellers may find misleading symbolic standardi-
zation profitable.
The Ackerlof phenomena probably played a role in the initial acceptance
of standards by hospitals in the early twentieth century. It also undoubtedly
has contributed to the increasing interest of nursing homes in standardization.
The nursing home industry has suffered extensive negative publicity in the last
decade"' and is increasingly experiencing competition from the home health
care industry."' If consumers of nursing home care accepted JCAH accredita-
tion with the same respect it has received in the hospital field, accreditation
could have a significant positive effect on the image of the industry and thus on
demand for its product.
In sum, seller standardization probably provides only minimal assurances
of quality to consumers of the services of medical care institutions. As institu-
tional medical care is usually urgently necessary, difficult for consumers to
evaluate, and without readily available substitutes, sellers will, for the reasons
just discussed, seldom have substantial incentives for creating or enforcing
standards that will increase the quality of their product above a fairly minimal
level.
E.
Causes of Inefficient or Efficiency Neutral Standardization and Certification
To this point we have focused on the contributions of standardization and
certification programs to efficiency, and discussed conditions under which cer-
tification and standardization programs may emerge that will enhance the utili-
ty of standardized goods and services to the ultimate consumer. Unfortunately,
standardization and certification programs may also emerge that make little
contribution to efficiency, or even that are seriously inefficient.
First, sellers may establish standardization or certification programs to
avoid or co-opt government regulation."' If public concern about the quality
deficiencies of a particular product — especially deficiencies that threaten
health or safety — reaches the level where government action seems inevitable,
292 See
Weingast,
supra
note 277, at 92, 93.
253
See, e.g.,
M. MENDELSON, TENDER LOVING GREED (1974); F. Moss & V. HAL-
AMANDRIS,
Too OLD,
Too Sicx, Too
BAD (1977).
25
Many current nursing home residents could be cared for in their own homes or in
other non-medical settings given adequate home health care.
See
B.
VLADECK, UNLOVING
CARE,
221-23 (1980); Butler,
Financing Noninstitutional Long-Term Care Services for the Elderly and
Chronically Ill: Alternatives to Nursing Homes,
13 CLEARINGHOUSE REV. 335, 335-40 (1979). Recent
amendments to the Medicare statute greatly expand the availability of home health care services
to elderly persons currently in nursing homes.
See
Pub. Law No. 96-499 S.§ 930b, 930g, 94 Stat.
2599, 2631-2633 (codified at 42 U.S.C. § 1395d(a)(3), 1395(K)(a)(2)(A) (Supp. IV, 1980)).
285
D, HEMENWAY,
supra note 221, at 68-70.
870
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
a threatened industry may act first to develop a standardization program,
either out of fear of adverse effects of bureaucratic government administra-
tion"' or of uncomfortably rigorous government definitions of quality, or both.
While such a program may in fact make a market function more efficiently and
enhance product quality, its main goal is political rather than economic. If,
therefore, political pressure can be relieved by symbolic rather than real quality
control, the program may contribute less to consumer utility than would gov-
ernment regulation.
This preemptive form of standardization-may be illustrated in the history
of the JCAH. The AHA became a member of the JCAH in 1950, immediately
following the great expansion of hospital licensing programs in the late
1940's.
287
There are some who believe that the program implemented
thereafter was less demanding of health care institutions than was the ACS pro-
gram that preceded it.
2
" Similarly, JCAH began accrediting nursing homes in
the late 1960's, just as the government began to discuss the need for increased
regulation of nursing homes under the Medicaid program.'" JCAH has con-
sistently held itself out to the industry as an attractive alternative to govern-
ment regulation.'" It has also been put forward as a single alternative to the
host of public and private programs that regulate various aspects of hospital
care,'" and its accreditation program has been widely relied on by federal and
state government regulators.
292
Standardization and certification programs that are efficiency neutral or
inefficient from a consumer perspective may emerge for a second reason. Sel-
lers may establish standardization and certification programs to avoid disputes
and limit liability."' To the extent that sellers can create consumer acceptance
of standards or certification, sellers will be less likely to incur disputes with or
liability to consumers regarding certified standard products. If sellers can con-
vince courts to judge their products by industry created quality standards,
286
See
Katz,
Industry Self-regulation: A Viable Alternative to Government Regulation
in KATZ ,
PROTECTING THE CONSUMER INTEREST 167, 168 (1976) (claiming that industries may prefer
self regulation, even if its substantive effects are more rigorous than government regulation,
because of a psychological preference for dealing with peers).
'a'
See supra
text accompanying notes 125-29. That the AHA played a major role in
drafting the model licensing act may cast doubt on this explanation of the AHA's behavior, but
may, alternatively, demonstrate that the AHA adopted several strategies to coopt regulation.
288
See
GERBER,
supra
note 107, at 130-31.
289
See
B.
VLADECK,
supra
note 284, at 59-69. For an alternative explanation of JCAH
involvement in nursing home accreditation,
see
FELDSTEIN, ASSOCIATION,
supra
note 271, at
158-59. Feldstein argues that hospitals attempted to use JCAH accreditation of nursing homes as
a means of controlling competition from nursing homes.
290
See
Affeldt,
supra
note 45, at 95 (1981); Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 189-91; Affeldt,
supra
note 190, at 52; Porterfield,
supra
note 54, at 20; Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 9, 10; Schlicke, supra
note 72, at 384-85; Schlicke,
supra
note 180, at 28.
29
'
See
1980
GAO
REPORT,
supra
note 212, at 2.
292 See supra
text accompanying and authorities cited at notes 57-71.
293
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 73-74.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
871
sellers may lessen their adjudicated liability."' It is, therefore, possibly not
coincidental that the JCAH push for hospital output quality control followed
closely on the heels of the revolutionary changes that resulted in the mid-1960's
when
Darling v. Charleston Hospital Association"'
found a hospital liable for physi-
cian malpractice.
Standards created under these conditions will undoubtedly have some
tendency to enhance consumer utility, for if they did not they would stand little
chance of being accepted by the courts. But, because of the substantial costs of
establishing the meaning of negligence through independent expert testimony
or economic analysis, judges may generally find it expedient to rely on industry
standards to define reasonable care rather than independently to create new
standards on a case by case basis.
296
Accordingly, industry standards may find
judicial acceptance despite the fact that they ultimately may bring about lower
quality products than would independent adjudications, if such adjudications
were costless
.
297
Finally, standardization and certification programs may be used, or
perhaps even created, to facilitate efforts to suppress competition.
298
If stand-
ards are widely publicized and accepted, the sponsors of the standards may be
able to exclude from the market potential competitors who produce non-stand-
ard goods.
299
Moreover, if standardization and certification are enforced by an-
cillary means of policing, exclusion can become quite coercive and effective.
For example, in
Radiant Burners v. People Gas & Electric,
300
the plaintiff's non-
standard burner was not only denied certification, but also persons using the
burners were refused gas by natural gas producers."' The plaintiff's product
was thus eliminated from the market.
The target of an anticompetitive standardization or certification program
will depend on the sponsor of the program. First, if the program is originated,
as most are, by a group of intermediate producers, it may limit access to the in-
294
Cf.
Jackson,
The Subject was Standards, 10
AKRON L. Rev. 185, 187-89, 216-18 (1976)
(arguing that industries lobby for federal standards legislation to limit their products liability ex-
posure).
295
33 lll. 2d 326, 211 N.E.2d 253 (1965),
cert. denied,
383 U.S. 946 (1966).
See
Schlicke,
supra
note 180, at 24.
296
The difficulties of proving medical negligence no doubt are a major contributor to the
substantial administrative costs of the malpractice litigation system. It has been estimated that
lawyers consume over half of the malpractice insurance premium dollar.
See
S.
LAW & S. POLAN,
supra
note 174, at 88.
29a
standards for medical practice may also put some limits on the practice of
defensive medicine, a major factor in the high cost of medical care.
298
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 76-78.
See
G. LAMB & C. SHIELDS, TRADE
ASSOCIATION LAW AND PRACTICE, 78-84 (1971); FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note
223, at 113-88.
299
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, ar. 55, 161; D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 77.
'" 364 U.S. 656 (1961).
"
1
Id.
at 658.
872
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol.
24:835
itial product by other competing intermediate producers or standardize the in-
itial product in such a way that it is useless to competitors."
2
Second, if the
program is originated by sellers, they may use it so as to eliminate products
that compete with their products."' Third, because the production of informa-
tion is a natural monopoly, a standardization program may itself either inten-
tionally or unintentionally exclude competing standardization programs. The
elimination of alternative sources of certification may, in turn, assist the spon-
sors of the program by discouraging the production of competing uncertified
products.
As JCAH is responsive to both intermediate producer and seller constitu-
encies, it could potentially suppress competition in all three of these respects.
First, insofar as JCAH limits competition on behalf of its intermediate pro-
ducer constituency, the physicians, it does so through its standardization of
hospital medical staff organization. An early and continuing concern of first the
HSP and then JCAH has been the organization of medical staff.'" The
original constituents of the HSP were surgeons. Their economic interest lay in
requiring hospital organization along a closed staff model that would exclude
competition from general practitioners. This would have maximized the de-
mand for and income of surgeons. The fear of this possibility no doubt explains
much of the opposition of the AMA to the HSP during the first half of this cen-
tury, when the AMA's constituency was still largely general practitioners."'
The lingering fear of exclusion of general practitioners from hospital practice
by surgeons and other specialists also may explain the continuing opposition of
the general practitioner section of the AMA to the JCAH until the late
1960's.
306
In fact, despite early efforts by specialists to limit staff privileges, most
hospitals were open to almost all physicians at least until the late 1930's.
307
This very likely reflects the political power of general practitioners within the
health care professions until that point — the general practitioners were no
902
See
D. HEMENWAY,
supra
note 221, at 67, 68.
3
°
3
Id. at 77.
304
See supra
text accompanying notes 105, 111, 114. On the literature concerning anti-
competitive effects ofhospital staff organization, see: W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at IV-1-IV-76;
Dolan & Ralston,
Hospital Admitting Privileges and the Sherman Act,
18 HOus. L. REV. 707 (1981);
Kissam, et al.,
supra
note 276; Comment,
Denial of Open Staff Hospital Privileges: An Anti-Trust
Scrutiny,
26 ST. LOUIS U. L.J. 751 (1982).
Cf.
on staff privileges generally M. ROEMER & D.
FRIEDMAN,
supra
note 111; Southwick,
supra
note 276, at 427-65 (1978); Groseclose,
Hospital
Privilege Cases: Braving the Dismal Swamp,
26 S.D.L. REV. 1 (1981).
305
See supra
text accompanying notes 116-22;
see DAVIS, supra
note 90, at 133, E.
RAYACK, PROFESSIONAL POWER AND AMERICAN MEDICINE: THE ECONOMICS OF THE
AMERICAN MEDICAL ASSOCIATION, 41-43 (1967); M. ROEMER & D. FRIEDMAN,
supra
note
111, at 38.
"
6
See supra
text accompanying notes 137-39, 149-50; F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 123-32,
see also
E. RAYACK,
supra
note 305, at 230.32; R. STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 252 (general practi-
tioner opposition to restricted staff privileges).
3°7
STEVENS,
supra
note 86, at 163, 253; Dolan & Ralston,
supra
note 304, at 724, 725.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
873
doubt politically able to stop the surgeons who controlled the HSP from using it
to exclude competition from the general practitioners. That hospitals have
become increasingly selective in granting staff privileges to physicians is surely
attributable in part to the increasing power of specialists within the medical
professions.'" Because JCAH has had to respond to a broad constituency of
both generalist and specialist physicians, its impact on staff privileges has not
been consistently to the advantage of either group. It has played a major role in
the growing articulation and rigor of staff privilege requirements, but has also
opened up hospitals to physicians through its standards requiring fair con-
sideration of staff privilege applications.
309
JCAH has also responded to its physician constituency by playing a major
role iri limiting the role of non-physician health care practitioners in hospitals.
The Accreditation Manual for Hospitals (AMH) recognizes several categories of
staff privileges. Under the AMH, members of the medical staff may admit pa-
tients to the hospital and supervise their care within it.
310
Moreover, active
medical staff also play a major role in hospital governance."" Unless provided
otherwise by state law, only physicians (medical doctors or osteopaths) or den-
tists may be members of the medical staff.
312
Podiatrists may be granted clini-
cal privileges, permitting them to provide medical care in a hospital, but podia-
trist admissions and discharges must be supervised by a physician.
313
Only "li-
censed practitioners," that is, physicians, dentists or podiatrists, may have
direct responsibility for diagnosis and treatment of patients; other health pro-
fessionals may not admit patients and may provide medical care only if super-
vised by a licensed physician.
3
'
4
JCAH standards assure, therefore, that accredited hospitals will primarily
rely on physicians to be responsible for patient care and to provide governance
through the medical staff structure. JCAH standards lirriit to a subordinate role
psychologists, chiropractors, midwives, nurse practitioners and other non-
physician practitioners who compete with physicians. Yet many of these practi-
tioners may need access to hospitals for certain aspects of their practice if they
are to compete with physicians: the psychologist to provide a controlled en-
vironment for observing or stabilizing a difficult patient; the midwife for a
delivery that threatens to become complicated.'`s
9o8 See
W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at IV-3 t-IV-39 for a discussion of the effects of staff
privilege controls on limiting the practices of generalists and of certain specialists.
"
9
See
authorities cited
supra
note 276.
3
' Q
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xviii, 93.
31
' Id.
at 100-09.
3
'
2
Id.
at 93.
3
"
Id.
at xviii, 97.
31 *
Id.
at xviii, 209;
see also
W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at IV-15-IV-16; Affeldt,
Accredita-
tion Clinic: JCAH Requirements for Delineation of Clinical Privileges and Duties,
9
HOSP. MED. STAFF,
Feb. 1980, at 7 (discussing effect of JCAH staff privilege standards on non-physicians). If state
law requires admission of non-physician practitioners to medical staff privileges, the standard
would also permit them admitting privileges,
see
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xviii, 93.
313
See
Lavine,
Memorandum Supporting Investigation of Joint Commissions on Accreditation of
874
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
Because of the practical necessity of accreditation for a hospital to func-
tion, JCAH accreditation is a powerful tool for limiting competition against
physicians in the hospital setting and thus for limiting competition against
physicians generally.'" JCAH may, by thus restraining competition, increase
the cost of health care.'" It is not surprising that JCAH is currently involved in
litigation on several fronts concerning its role in controlling staff privileges in
hospitals.'"
JCAH not only limits the role of non-physician practitioners in hospitals
but also does so in a variety of other institutional settings. The "all or none"
policy of JCAH requires that all facilities operated by a JCAH accredited in-
stitution be JCAH accredited as a condition for any part of the institutions to
retain JCAH accreditation.
319
Under this policy, .a hospital that includes a
distinct part facility for the developmentally disabled or a substance abuse pro-
gram also would have to limit staff privileges in its auxiliary programs to com-
ply with JCAH standards for those programs
32
° to retain accreditation for its
hospital program.
JCAH may not only limit competition against physicians, but also limit
competition against its seller constituent members: the hospitals. If hospitals
can get state legislatures or private insurance companies to license or pay for
only those health care services delivered by JCAH accredited facilities, where
those services delivered could also be provided in a non-institutional or non-
medical program, the hospitals can exclude competition from the non-
accredited programs. For example, a recent legislative proposal in Ohio per-
mitted insurance companies to use JCAH standards as an alternative to state
certification for determining reimburseability of substance abuse programs.
Opponents contended that use of JCAH standards might require delivery of
these services in institutions using a medical model and exclude social service-
oriented substance abuse programs.
321
Hospitals and American Medical Associations,
submitted to the FTC, July 12, 1976, at 29-34; W.
Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at IV-40-IV-42, IV-50; Grad,
Allied Health Professionals and Hospital
Privileges,
10 L. MED.
&
HEALTH CARE 165, 165 (1982).
Cf.
Blue Shield of Va. v. McCready,
102 S. Ct. 2540 (1982) acknowledging competition between psyChologists and psychiatrists.
216
W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at IV-5, IV-7.
3
"
Id.
at IV-19-IV-20, IV-50-IV-52, IV-54-IV-55.
316
cases cited
supra note 217.
3"
See
AMH,
supra
note 39, at
xx.
32°
Staff privilege standards for mental health facilities arc set forth in the CON-
SOLIDATED STANDARDS,
supra
note 40.
These standards are, on the whole, considerably more open than those of the AMH, and
permit staff privileges for not only physicians, but also for clinical psychologists, social workers,
psychiatric workers and substance abuse workers.
5
9.2.1. They do, however, maintain a central
role for physicians in diagnosis, SS 3.1, 1.10.3.11, and professional staff governance, 5 3.7.2.1.
Moreover, the JCAH is currently considering evaluating all. hospital based mental health
facilities under the AMH, a move that could strengthen the hand of physicians in those facilities.
321
Telephone interview with David Shover, Director of Operations, Council on Ac-
creditation (September 8, 1982), regarding Subst. Sen. Bill 336 S 3923.28 (1982) (codified at
Ohio Rev. Code S 3923.28 (Baldwin)).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
875
Finally, through its all or none policy JCAH can limit competition against
itself from rival accrediting programs. If a hospital operating a substance abuse
program must have the program accredited by JCAH to maintain its hospital
accreditation, the hospital is unlikely to seek additional accreditation for the
program from the Council on Accreditation, a social service oriented accredita-
tion agency which also accredits substance abuse programs."'
F.
Reasons Why Standardization and Certification Programs Beneficial to Intermediate
Producers and Sellers May Not Optimize Consumer Utility
Standardization programs originated to enhance the utility of initial prod-
ucts to intermediate producers may fail to optimize the utility of those products
for ultimate consumers. First, a standardization or certification program neces-
sarily requires identification of some products as standard, others as non-
standard. If consumers must rely on standards or certificates for consumption
decisions, either because of the complexity of a product or because enforcement
methods — such as licensing requirements — eliminate the possibility of con-
sumer choice, consumers will not buy non-standard products even though they
may better suit some consumers. Any standardization or certification program
will thus narrow consumer choices and cause some consumers to buy products
that are not suited to their needs.'" Some consumers may have preferred to
have lower cost, lower quality products available, others just different prod-
ucts. If JCAH requires all hospitals to provide certain services, a consumer
must go to a hospital with such services, even though they are useless to that
consumer and may increase the costs of hospitalization.
Second, if a standardized or certified product is complex, and the quality
standardization program relies on many criteria, it is likely that the program
will err in providing products of too high or too low quality in some respect.
324
If standards permit some aspects of the product to be of low quality, consumers
will derive less utility from that aspect of the product. If standards require ex-
cessive quality as to some product characteristics, consumers may have to pay
for quality of no use to them.
If a standardization and certification program is initiated by intermediate
producers, both the problem of non-availability of non-standard goods and the
problem of error as experienced by the ultimate consumer may be exacerbated.
If the market power of the intermediate producer is sufficiently strong, or if the
program is enforced independently, the initial producer may eliminate non-
standard initial products that may independently be of use to the ultimate con-
sumer but do not enhance the utility of the intermediate producer's product.
Moreover, the program may discourage the initial producer from producing
322
COUNCIL ON ACCREDITATION, PROVISIONS FOR ACCREDITATION, 80-84 (1982).
323
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223,
at
55, 56; J. GELMAN,
supra
note
226, at 135.
32
'
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, at 567-69.
876
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
products that could be useful to competitors of the intermediate producer. If in-
termediate producers use standardization as a means to deny the initial prod-
uct to competing producers of substitute final products, the consumer may be
denied access to a final product he prefers. Finally, a standardization and cer-
tification program initiated by an intermediate producer will not necessarily in-
crease the utility of the product of the intermediate producer to the ultimate
consumer. In relation to the ultimate consumer, intermediate producers are
sellers; intermediate producers will assure the quality of their own product
through standardization only to the extent that it is independently in their in-
terest to do so as sellers.
325
Similar effects may result from the standardization
of complementary products.
This analysis may provide insight into the effect of JCAH standards on
quality of institutional health care as experienced by the ultimate consumer:
the patient. JCAH was initiated by surgeons and a majority of the commis-
sioners are still physicians and surgeons. The analysis above would suggest
that JCAH standards, and the hospitals developed to comply with them, would
be structured to assure high quality initial inputs to be used by or to comple-
ment the services of physicians and surgeons. Accordingly, it is not surprising
that JCAH standards have been criticized frequently for excessive emphasis on
the quality of medical care inputs as opposed to the quality of actual medical
outcomes in accredited hospitals.
325
The hospital, the major product of JCAH
standardization, has also been criticized for relying excessively on costly, com-
plex, and technological forms of medical care"' that increase the demand for
and the price of physician or surgeon services. The hospital appears to have
been organized largely for the convenience and welfare of the physician rather
than the patient.
328
This analysis also explains deficiencies critics have identified in the JCAH
survey and accreditation program. First, JCAH accreditation inspections are
arranged beforehand with ample warning to the institutions, assuring that
JCAH only sees the institution at its best behavior and not in its normal condi-
3"
Set supra
text accompanying notes 277-78, 285-86, 293-94, 298-303, discussing cir-
cumstances in which sellers may standardize or certify their products.
326
Wyatt Brief,
,supra
note 67, at 10-14; J. Feder,
supra
note 164, at 8; Gelman,
supra
note 226, at 128; A. GERBER,
supra
note 107, at 130-136; S. LAW & S. POLAN,
supra
note 174, at
58, 64; A. Somers,
supra
note 127, at 106; Crosby,
supra
note 54, at 133-35; Gerber,
Surgical Pros
and Cons,
135 SURD. GYNCOL. OBSTE. 431, 432 (1972); Worthington & Silver,
supra
note 176, at
312;
Suit Challenges, supra
note 101, at 186.
322
This criticism has been voiced both from the perspectives of concerns about the cost
of care,
see
Havighurst & Blumstein,
supra
note 1, at 25-30; Cohodes,
supra
note 3, at 65-66;
Rosenblatt,
supra
note 1, at 1094-1106, and concerns about quality, see V. SIDEL
&
R. SIDEL, A
HEALTHY STATE, 69-78 (1977); ILLICH, MEDICAL NEMESIS: THE EXPROPRIATION OF HEALTH
18-25 (1975).
328
See
Pauly & Redisch,
The Not-For-Profit Hospital as a Physician Cooperative,
63 AM.
ECON. REV. 63, 87-99 (1973); Redisch,
supra
note 271, at 218-31; Saltman & Young,
supra
note
274, at 406-10.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
877
don.'" Second, a two hour public information interview provides the only op-
portunity for hospital staff and consumer representatives to participate in the
JCAH survey process. Moreover, hospital administrators are normally present
at this interview, a factor that may intimidate hospital staff members."'" JCAH
further limits hospital staff and consumer input into accreditation decisions by
permitting hospital employees and staff and consumer representatives no fur-
ther opportunity to participate in the accreditation process, rebut administra-
tion claims, or review a decision to grant accreditation."' JCAH provides a
lengthy appeal process during which a hospital denied accreditation may con-
tinue to operate as though accredited."' Dissatisfaction with these procedures
and their results is evidenced by the charges of inadequacy leveled at the JCAH
surveys."' The inspection process itself takes place only once every three years
and, under new JCAH survey procedures, may even rely on self-survey to
assure the correction of violations identified by the inspection process.
334
Final-
ly, JCAH does not require facilities to meet all, or indeed any, of its re-
quirements or standards, but only to "substantially comply" with the stand-
ards as a whole.'"
JCAH has responded to these criticisms principally by asserting that they
are based on a misunderstanding of JCAH's role. JCAH perceives itself not as
an enforcer, but rather as a consultant or educator whose role is to encourage
and inspire hospitals voluntarily to deliver high quality care.
336
JCAH asserts
that its primary role is to assure that hospitals have the capacity to deliver care
rather than to guarantee that such care is in fact delivered."'
Both the criticisms of JCAH and its response are not surprising, given that
JCAH is a standardization and certification program enacted by sellers and by
"9
House hearings, supra
note 64, at 6;
Senate hearings, supra
note 53, at 38, 44, 103-05;
Hearings, supra
note 54, at 1904; Wyatt Brief,
supra
note 67, at 15; Rubin,
The Accreditation of
Hospitals, What Does it Promise?,
HEALTH L. PROD. LIB. BULL. 90, 93 (1980).
930
See
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xx; xxi; Rubin,
supra note 320, at 94.
See also
Misericordia
Hospital Medical Center v. NLRB, 623 F.2d 808 (2d Cir. 1980) (sustaining an NLRB order
reinstating a nurse fired for testifying at a JCAH public information interview).
"' See Hearings, supra
note 54, at 1905; Wyatt Brief,
supra
note 67, at 15-17; Rubin,
supra
note 329, at 94.
992
Rubin,
supra
note 329, at 96.
933
See
Wyatt Brief,
supra
note 67, at 8-19;
Senate hearings, supra
note 64, at 38, 66, 68;
House hearings, supra note 64, at 56-60.
"4
See
Wyatt Brief,
supra
note 67, at 16, and authorities cited
supra
at note 216. JCAH
does accept complaints regarding hospitals from patients or staff and, on occasion, makes unan-
nounced inspections based on such complaints. Telephone interview with Eleanor Wagner and
Daniel Schuyler, attorneys for JCAH, Dec. 9, 1982. However, recent hearings brought out that
JCAH only received 24 complaints in 2 years
(Senate hearings, supra
note 64, at 104) (compare the
3400 complaints received by the California Health Department over a one year period
(id.
at
45)). Moreover, though JCAH has made some unannounced surveys in response to complaints
(id.
at 104), it handles many complaints by asking the facility to investigate itself
(id.
at 39, 116;
House hearings, supra
note 64, at 81).
3"
See
authorities cited
supra
note 51.
"6
See
authorities cited
supra
note 54.
337 Hearings, supra
note 54, at 1901.
878
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol.
24:835
complementary and intermediate producers. Physicians and surgeons who
practice in the hospital setting are not as interested in the final product the
hospital delivers as they are in the capacity of the hospital to support their own
production of services.
338
While infrequent announced inspections may not
guarantee continued high quality care, they are adequate to insure that the
hospital will be organized along the lines set out in the JCAH standards, and
that physician goals can be met within the hospital. It is not in the interests of
physicians or surgeons to have an accreditation program that would monitor
their own performance or be a constant intrusive presence in the hospital, in-
terfering with their practice.'" The institutions also have no interest in a more
intrusive inspection program or higher standards. As long as the JCAH pro-
gram is adequate. to avoid political pressure for more intensive government
regulation, and, perhaps, to keep the worst violators of consensus standards
out of operation, institutions ought to be satisfied."°
This is not to say, however, that the JCAH accreditation program has not
had or cannot have a positive affect on the quality of care patients receive from
hospitals. Weaknesses in the inspection system need not mean that hospitals do
not in fact comply with the standards. Insofar as the standards address major
administrative systems or physical plant characteristics, it is unlikely that com-
pliance will fluctuate markedly over the three year accreditation period, or that
a hospital seriously out of compliance will be able to achieve compliance solely
for the purposes of an accreditation inspection."' •
Empirical and anecdotal evidence concerning the effect of JCAH stand-
ards on the quality of hospital care is inconclusive. JCAH accreditation of
hospitals with serious quality deficiencies played a prominent role in consumer
criticisms of JCAH in the early 1970's.
342
Implementation of the JCAH quality
audit, the centerpiece of its quality control system, has been criticized as inade-
quate."' Research has found low correlations between JCAH accreditation
and other measures of hospital quality.'" and wide variations in quality be-
'" See supra
text accompanying notes 270-74.
'" Id.
340
See supra
text accompanying notes 277-97.
3
" It is instructive that in 1970, 74% of all hospitals inspected received full accreditation
but that only 45% of the hospitals inspected for the first time did so. Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at
381. Hospitals apparently find it easier to maintain compliance with accreditation standards than
to initially meet them.
]42
BRESLOW,
QUALITY
AND COST CONTROL: MEDICARE AND BEYOND IN THE AD-
MINISTRATION OF MEDICARE: A SHARED RESPONSIBILITY, 17, 30, 31 (B.
Smith & N.
Hol-
lander
eds. 1973); Worthington & Silver,
supra
note 176, at 312-13;
see Hospital Accreditation, supra
note 192, at 3;
Suit Challenges, supra
note 178, at 187.
3
"
See
Escovitz, Burkeitt, Kuhn, Zeleznic & Gonnella,
The Effects of Mandatory Quality
Assurance,
16 MED. CARE, Nov. 1978, at 941.
"4
J.
NEUHAUSER, THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ADMINISTRATIVE ACTIVITIES AND
HOSPITAL PERFORMANCE 60-69, 100
(1971);
see also
Roemer, Mostafa & Hopkins,
A Proposed
Hospital Quality Index: Hospital Death Rate Adjusted for Cast Severity,
3
HEALTH
SERV. RESEARCH 96,
115 (1968) (finding little difference in quality between accredited and unaccredited hospitals).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
879
tween JCAH accredited hospitals.'" Nevertheless, overall consumer satisfac-
tion with medical care remains high
346
and JCAH itself continues to enjoy
general respect.
347
G.
Non-Accountability of Self-Regulation
A final basis for criticizing self-regulatory standardization and certifica-
tion programs is their lack of accountability to the public, a factor not directly
related to efficiency. Inefficient regulation may to some extent be excused if a
regulatory program advances public policy goals other than efficiency, such as
distributional equity or public participation. Industry self-regulation lacks,
however, a commitment to these goals. JCAH claims that it is responsible pri-
marily to its members and the institutions that it accredits, not to the public.'"
JCAH asserts this even though it has accepted a major role in federal and state
programs regulating health care, a role responsible for much of its growth over
the last two decades.'"
Few opportunities for public participation in either its standardization or
its accreditation programs are provided by JCAH. Its consumer advisory coun-
cil was short-lived. Its one "public" member was added only recently and can-
not seriously be considered a representative of health care consumers.
35
° It has
been claimed that representation and participation of consumers in the ac-
creditation councils may have been a significant factor in JCAH's disbanding
the councils and establishing the PTAC system."' Since the early 1970's,
JCAH has allowed some consumer participation in its accreditation inspections
through its public information interviews, but this participation is strictly
limited, and JCAH still makes no provision for consumer appeals of accredita-
tion decisions.
352
34
' See
Longest,
Administrative Coordination in General Hospitals,
Georgia State University,
School of Business Administration, Research Monograph No. 55 (1973)
cited
in P. O'DONO-
GHUE, EVIDENCE ABOUT THE EFFECTS OF HEALTH CARE REGULATION 86 (1974).
346
See Anderson, Fleming & Champney,
Exploring a Paradox: Belief in a Crisis and General
Satisfaction with Medical Care,
59 MILLBANK MEMORIAL FUND Q. 329 (1982).
347
See, e.g. ,
1979 and 1980 GAO Reports urging substitution of JCAH accreditation for
state licensure; People v. Barksdale, 8 Cal.3d 320, 336-37, 503 P.2d 257, 269-70, 105 Cal. Rptr.
1, 13-14 (1972);
Senate hearings, supra
note 53, at 16 (testimony of Carolyn Davis, Administrator,
Health Care Financing Administration),
3"
See
authorities cited
supra
note 54.
349
About 30-32% of the survey fees paid JCAH are reimbursed by the federal govern-
ment. GAO REPORT,
supra
note 207, at 5. More important, the prominent role of JCAH in
federal and state regulation undoubtedly explains much of its growth since 1965. See
supra
text
accompanying note 170.
"° JCAH's first public member, appointed in 1981, is a governor of a hospital, presi-
dent of a telephone company and director of several corporations including a major Chicago
bank.
See BOC Selects First Public Member,
JCAH PERSPECTIVES, Nov.-Dec. 1981, at 4.
3
" Crosby,
supra
note 54, at 137 n.4.
"
2
See
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xx-xxi describing JCAH's public information interview
procedure. Persons wishing to testify at the public informatidn interview must request the right to
do so in writing. The request must be received by JCAH at least two working days before the
880
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
The
most serious failure of JCAH with respect to public accountability is
its refusal to provide public access to information. As related earlier, JCAH
maintains strict confidentiality regarding its survey records, and has gone so
far as to sue the federal government to maintain the confidentiality of these
records.
353
The question of availability of survey information if deemed
Medicaid certification status is to be accorded to accredited nursing homes con-
tinues to be a major issue in that policy decision.'" The JCAH policy of con-
fidentiality not only decreases the accountability of JCAH and of the
hospitals it regulates to the public, but also diminishes the possibilities for com-
petition between health care providers by not disclosing information to con-
sumers that might permit consumers to make more informed decisions among
competing providers.
Considering the earlier analysis,
555
none of this is surprising. If JCAH has
been created to serve the needs of a constituency of physicians and surgeons
and a constituency. of institutions, there is no reason for it to become account-
able to the public, encourage public participation, or make its operations and
records public. Not having been formed to serve the public, JCAH is not ac-
countable to the public.
III.
JCAH: BENEFITS AND PROBLEMS
At this point it is appropriate to stop and draw up a balance sheet based on
what the economics of the information model reveals about JCAH. Having
done this, it will be possible to evaluate JCAH as compared to alternative
means of quality control.
survey begins. JCAH notifies the hospital of all requests for public information interviews and
hospital representatives are expected to attend. The public information interview takes place on
the first survey day and normally does not exceed two hours in length. Any further participation
in the survey by outside sources of information must be authorized by the hospital.
See Hearings,
supra
note 54, at 1990, at which then director Porterfield testified that turning the accreditation
process into an adversary procedure by allowing consumer appeals would destroy the "internal
quality promotion mechanism" of the JCAH.
See also
Rubin,
supra
note 329, at 94 (criticizing the
JCAH inspection process).
3
" See supra
text accompanying note 193; Affeldt, Maintaining
Confidentiality of Survey Data,
56
HOSP.,
Sept. 16, 1982, at 70; Affeldt,
Accreditation Problems: Confidentiality of Survey Reports,
53
HOSP. Mar. 16, 1979, at 44 (hereinafter cited as
Confidentiality).
JCAH defends its confidentiality
policy in part by claiming that the public is incapable of understanding survey information.
Lewis,
supra
note 190, at 20, 21.
9
S
4
See
47 Fed. Reg. at 23406 (1982), Letters, from John E. Affeldt, president of JCAH
to Edward L. Kelley, acting director Health Standards and Quality Bureau (Dec. 2, 1980) in-
sisting on confidentiality of accreditation survey reports and reply from Kelley to Affeldt (Jan.
30, 1981) affirming the critical need for disclosure of survey records before HHS could grant
JCAH accredited nursing homes deemed status for Medicare and Medicaid certification.
See also
Senate hearings, supra
note 53, at 16, 64-65, 102, 241,
House hearings, supra
note 64, at 76 (discussing
JCAH confidentiality policy).
"5
See supra, §§
IIA-IIF.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
881
First, on the positive side of the ledger:
1)
JCAH standards assure the organization of hospitals so as to maximize
the utility of hospitals to physicians and surgeons. Derivatively, the standards
in some instances increase the utility of hospitals to patients. They do so first by
identifying and describing factors that assure the quality of inputs necessary for
physician care in hospitals. For the reasons discussed earlier,"
6
it is much more
efficient for a single entity to do this than for
,
each physician, acting as an
atomistic consumer, to identify these attributes through his own search and ex-
perience. Second, JCAH, through its accreditation program, assisted by an-
cillary enforcement tools both public and private — such as licensure re-
quirements — assures that institutions are organized to enhance the quality of
these inputs. Third, and perhaps most important, JCAH standards give physi-
cians a controlling role in many aspects of hospital organization. In particular,
the standards require self-governing, organized hospital medical staffs, with in-
itial responsibility for staff appointments and quality control."' Through these
JCAH requirements physicians have created a structure perhaps unparalleled
elsewhere in industrial organization. JCAH standards assure physicians a
prominent role in administering aspects of the hospital relevant to their prac-
tice without requiring them to assume economic or general administrative
responsibility for the hospital. Hospitals must accept this arrangement because
of ancillary private and public enforcement devices, including government
licensure and Medicare certification. Thus to the extent that physicians' serv-
ices are useful to hospital patients, JCAH assures that those services will be
delivered in a context that provides optimal inputs for those services.
2)
Hospital participation in JCAH further assures patients an adequate
level of care in accredited hospitals. Hospitals are motivated to use standards to
maintain a sufficiently high average level of quality to assure confidence in and
demand for their services, to minimize political pressure for increased regula-
tion and to minimize tort liability. They will therefore generally be motivated
to exercise their power within JCAH to maintain at least a minimally adequate
level of quality in hospitals.
3)
JCAH operates efficiently. JCAH can get by with a minimal inspection
program because the bulk of standards enforcement is achieved through physi-
cians and administrators within the hospital. As JCAH standards promote the
self-interest of physicians and hospitals, they are largely self-enforcing. JCAH
is a consultant, not an enforcer. Moreover, because JCAH is responsive to the
industry, it can draw heavily on industry expertise at a
minimal
cost and effi-
ciently create and review standards. There is some empirical evidence of such
35
€ See
discussion of problems faced by consumer standardization efforts, supra text ac-
companying notes 229.35, much of which would apply to physicians acting as individual con-
sumers.
"' See
AMH,
supra
note 39, at xviii, 103-05, 151-54, 209.
882
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
efficiency. The 1979 GAO Report relates that state validation inspections cost
on the average $150 more than JCAH accreditation surveys.'"
4) Finally, the standards would appear to minimize regulatory inefficien-
cies. A frequent complaint about regulation is that it creates inefficiencies in
the regulated industry.
359
As JCAH is accountable to the institutional medical
care industry, such inefficiencies ought to be minimal. JCAH analyzes its
regulations for cost effectiveness, and attempts to allow hospitals maximum
flexibility in applying standards.
36
°
The negative side of the balance, however, also is weighty:
1)
JCAH provides little useful information to ultimate consumers about
accredited institutions. Consumer preferences in health care vary, but JCAH
provides consumers with almost no information to assist their choices.
2)
JCAH provides ultimate consumers with little protection as to the
quality of the medical care they receive. JCAH focuses on the quality of the in-
itial products physicians use in delivery of care, less on the quality of the final
product: physician/hospital services provided to patients.
3)
JCAH does not address the quality of services of non-institutional
health care services, as they are generally not accredited by JCAH. It addresses
poorly the issue of quality of care delivered by non-physician practitioners. Its
standards have the effect of excluding non-physician practitioners or subjecting
them to the supervision of physicians rather than of optimizing the use of their
skills.
4)
Moreover, the effects of JCAH standards on alternative health care
providers are anticompetitive. JCAH standards restrict significantly the role of
non-physician practitioners in hospital settings. JCAH accreditation also limits
health care delivery to institutional settings by excluding competing non-
institutional alternatives, insofar as accreditation is used as a requirement for
licensing or insurance payments.
5)
JCAH is less useful for identifying the quality of services of institutions
in which physicians are not involved. In institutions such as hospitals, where
physicians are heavily involved, the intermediate producer "cross-regulation"
aspects of JCAH counterbalance its self-regulatory aspects. For facilities like
nursing homes, however, where physician involvement is minima1,
36
' JCAH
represents pure self-regulation, and provides less protection for consumer in-
terests.
"a
See
GAO REPORT,
supra
note 207, at iii, 24-25,
but see Senate hearings, supra
note 53, at
46 (testimony of Mildred Simmons, deputy director of California Department of Health Service,
claiming that state inspections are less expensive).
359
See, e.g.,
McClure,
Structure, supra
note 1, at 136-39; Noll,
supra
note 1, at 38, 39.
365
See
Affeldt,
Cost Effective Health Care, How JCAH Will Help,
9
Hose.
MED. STAFF,
Apr. 1979, at 7-9.
"' See Mechanic &
Arkin,
A Cooperative Agenda for Medicine and Nursing,
307 NEW ENG. J.
MED. 747, 749 (1982).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
8B3
6) JCAH lacks the saving grace of availability for achieving public policy
goals other than efficiency. It is not open to public scrutiny, participation or
responsibility.
IV. ALTERNATIVES
The picture of JCAH that emerges at this point is mixed. Significant con-
tributions to efficiency and consumer welfare are counterbalanced by ineffi-
ciencies and an absence of accountability. With this assessment before us, we
can consider how JCAH compares to alternative means of quality regulation.
Some of these alternatives can be disposed of summarily. First, suppres-
sion of JCAH in favor of leaving hospital quality to be determined by a com-
pletely unregulated market does not seem warranted. The positive contribu-
tion of JCAH to maintaining health care quality is significant. The negative
aspects of JCAH, such as its anticompetitive effects, may perhaps be controlled
without suppressing JCAH itself. The major problem with JCAH's quality
standards is not that they are wrong, just incomplete.
Second, consumer accreditation does not seem an adequate alternative.
Though this alternative has much to commend it in theory, it is impractical.
For the reasons set out earlier,
962
the cost of standardization and certification of
medical care facilities would be high, the difficulties with consumers recaptur-
ing this cost by reselling information insurmountable. It is also unlikely that
consumers could assemble the expertise necessary to evaluate technically com-
plex health care, or even that they would be allowed admission to private
health care facilities for accreditation inspections. This is not to say that con-
sumers cannot play a significant role in assuring health care quality. It is,
however, unlikely that they could ever replace the JCAH.
There are, however, other, more viable options. A comprehensive federal
regulatory program could be established. Alternatively, JCAH could be made
a public body. Finally, JCAH as it stands could be supplemented and con-
trolled.
A.
Government Standardization and Accreditation
A first possibility is comprehensive federal government regulation of in-
stitutional medical care in addition to the JCAH program. Government
regulation of medical care institutions, of course, has already existed at the
state and local level for at least thirty to forty years. Almost all states now re-
quire hospitals and nursing homes to be licensed."
3
Nevertheless, state stand-
ards and inspections often are more superficial than those of JCAH.
364
And
362
See supra text
accompanying notes 229-35.
363
A. SOMERS,
supra
note 127, at 107 n.4.
See also
Lander,
supra
note 26, at 132, 133
(discussing hospital licensure).
364
GAO
REPORT,
supra
note 207, at 16-21; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 381; J. GELMAN,
884
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
many states, encouraged by the federal government, have moved towards rely-
ing on JCAH accreditation for state licensure.
365
There is currently no comprehensive federal government program for
standardizing and certifying medical care facilities. The Senate passed a bill in
1973 to establish a federal Commission of Quality of Health Care Assurance
which could have replaced the JCAH for the purpose of certifying facilities to
participate in federal programs.
366
The idea of such a commission has much to
commend it. It would presumably be more directly accountable and responsive
to the public interest than JCAH. It could easily be made subject to the
Freedom of Information Act
367
and to AdMinistrative Procedure Act rule-
making requirements,
368
thus assuring public access to information and public
participation in standard setting. It might also have less anticompetitive effects
than JCAH.
There are, however, reasons why the creation of such a program might be
unwise. As to a federal hospital regulatory program these arguments are quite
strong. First, it is probable that if a federal program were created the consti-
tuency of JCAH would retain JCAH as a separate parallel private program.
Certainly physicians would support a continued JCAH program to protect
their interests. A federal program would therefore constitute an expensive
duplication of the JCAH program. Because JCAH represents professional
organizations of substantial size and experience, and can consult with addi-
tional professional groups through its PTAC 's, it has access at minimal cost to
extensive and widely varied expertise. For a health care regulatory commission
to operate independently it would need to develop its own duplicate system of
experts at considerable cost.
369
Though the program could avoid this cost in-
itially by adopting JCAH standards, it would still need to develop its own ex-
pertise to update and enforce the standards. This duplication would of necessi-
ty be inefficient to the patient/taxpayer unless the benefits of the federal pro-
supra
note 226, at 126; Lewis,
supra
note 190, at 23; Worthington & Silver,
supra
note 176, at
308-310.
365
See
authorities cited
supra
notes 66-71, 212.
366
Health Maintenance Organization and Resources Act of 1973, S. 14 S 403, 93rd
Cong., 1st Sess. S. REP. NO. 129, 81-88 (1973),
reprinted in
Boggs,
"A Contextfor Quality Control,"
in THE MENTALLY RETARDED CITIZEN AND THE LAW, 357, at 370-371 (M. Kindred ed. 1976)
(the proposal passed the Senate but was dropped from the bill in the House,
see
Boggs,
supra
at
370).
Cf.
Clark,
Why Does Health Care Regulation Fail?, 41
MD. L. REV. 1, 26-28 (1981) (sug-
gesting the establishment of a Commission on Medical Technologies to provide some non-
physician control over medical decision making). The federal government has not always shown
interest in health care standardization. In 1913 the ACS petitioned the Public Health Service to
take over the hospital standardization effort. The government declined the offer, stating that
standardization was a task for the public sector. M.
ROEMER & D. FRIEDMAN,
supra
note 111, at
36.
367
See
5 U.S.C. 5 552(a)(2) (1976, Supp. IV 1980).
368
See
5 U.S.C. 5 553 (1976).
369
Henderson & Pearson,
Implementing Federal Environmental Policies, the Limits of Aspira-
tional Commands,
78 COL. L. REV. 1419, 1438 (1978); McClure,
Structure, supra
note 1, at 136;
Wolfson, Trebilcock & Thohy,
supra
note 235, at 211.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
885
gram were so significant as to justify the costs of establishing and operating a
duplicate program. It is generally believed, both at the federal and the state
level, that JCAH does a sufficiently adequate job of regulation of hospitals so
that such additional costs would not be justified.
32
°
A second problem is the potential lack of flexibility in a federal hospital
standardization effort. JCAH has responded to the constantly changing nature
of the technology of health care delivery by continually revising and updating
its standards. By contrast, the federal government basically adopted JCAH
standards for its small independent Medicare hospital certification program for
non-accredited hospitals in 1966
371
and has made only minor changes since.
372
While public rulemaking procedures facilitate public participation and ac-
countability, they are cumbersome and time-consuming and impose upon a
standardization program an inflexibility that would hinder regulation of a
rapidly evolving industry like institutional medical care.
373
Third and most significant, it has frequently been noted that regulatory
agencies have a tendency to favor the interests of organized regulated in-
dustries over those of diffuse and unorganized consumers.
374
This tendency is
particularly strong in the medical care industry, which has shown itself
remarkably adept at co-opting any programs designed to regulate it.
375
Hospi-
tal patients are singularly atomistic and unorganized; they have no common
characteristics to facilitate organization other than their idiosyncratic medical
problems. Accordingly, there is little ground for optimism that a federal
government regulatory agency would be any more responsive to consumer in-
terests or less responsive to hospitals than JCAH.
All of these arguments, however, carry much less force when applied to
regulation of nursing homes and perhaps of other non-hospital institutions.
First, JCAH nursing home accreditation is much less pervasive than is hospital
accreditation. Whereas the vast majority of hospitals are now subject to JCAH
accreditation, only 1,300 of the nation's 23,000 nursing homes are currently
JCAH accredited.
376
Six hundred of these are hospital based facilities.
377
JCAH nursing home accreditation has never been accepted by state licensing
970
authorities cited
supra note 347.
37
' J. FEDER, supra note 164, at 11; A. SOMERS, supra note 127, at 117.
372
Recent proposed changes in the federal program appear to aim at bringing it in line
with proposed JCAH changes.
See
48 Fed. Reg. 299 (1983).
373 P. HARTER,
supra
note 223, at 203-07 (1979); McClure,
Structure, supra
note 1, at
129-131; Noll, supra
note 1, at 35-38; Schlicke,
supra
note 51, at 384.
Cf
FELDSTEIN, HEALTH
CARE ECONOMICS, 241-242 (1979) (Feldstein argues that regulatory agencies resist change both
to limit their risks of failure and to protect regulated industries from competition and diminished
profitability).
374
McClure,
Structure, supra
note 1, at 122-26; Stewart,
The Reformation of American Ad-
ministrative Law,
88 HARV. L. REV. 1671, 1684-87 (1975).
378
See generally
Clark,
supra
note 366 (addressing the problem of physician co-option of
medical regulation).
"6
House hearings, supra
note 64, at 83; Punch.
sora
note 54. at 40.
37
Downey,
Nursing Homes vs. JCAH,
MODERN HEALTH CARE, April 1975, at 35.
886
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
agencies or for federal Medicare and Medicaid program certification purposes
as a "deemed" equivalent of state or federal inspection and approval. Virtual-
.l
.
y all states license nursing homes
378
and most nursing homes are certified to
participate in some federal program,
379
so government regulation is much more
pervasive than is JCAH accreditation. As to nursing homes, therefore, it is
clearly JCAH accreditation and not government regulation which is the dupli-
cative program. Second, the arguments based on lack of expertise and flexibili-
ty carry much less weight here. Nursing home care is much less technologically
complex than hospital care and is subject to less frequent and substantial
changes in technology. Further, the federal and state governments have
regulated nursing home care for some time and have had an opportunity to ac-
cumulate signifiCant expertise.
3
" In addition, the highly organized nature of
the senior citizen and nursing home consumer lobby makes it less likely that
regulatory agencies will become subservient to provider interests.
38
' Finally,
and most important, the internal guarantees that make JCAH a more accept-
able instrument for regulating hospitals are not applicable to nursing homes.
As the model developed earlier shows, the independent interests of physicians
and surgeons in hospital regulation, combined with their heavy representation
on the JCAH, assures that the hospital regulatory program at least guaran-
tees patients high quality theatres for the performance of physicians and
surgeons.
382
The presence and interest of physicians in nursing homes is mini-
mal,'" however, and thus physicians are much less likely to operate as a bal-
ancing force against the nursing home constituency within JCAH. JCAH nurs-
ing home regulation may well be an undesirable form of self-regulation.
In summary, JCAH accreditation may be superior to government regula-
tion for some purposes such as hospital accreditation, but not for other pur-
poses, such as nursing home regulation.
B.
Make JCAH a Public Body
A second option is to make JCAH function essentially like a government
entity. This could be done by making JCAH accountable to the public: open-
ing its board to public participation and its records and reports to the public.
578
See
T.
JOST,
MODEL RECOMMENDATIONS: INTERMEDIATE SANCTIONS FOR EN-
FORCEMENT OF QUALITY OF CARE IN NURSING HOMES, at 57-71 (1981).
"8
17,000 nursing homes participate in Medicaid,
House hearings, supra
note 64, at 79.
380
Most states adopted nursing home licensing statutes in the 1940's or earlier. F. Hair,
supra
note 72, at 246. The JCAH nursing home accreditation program did not begin until 1965.
Id.
at 148-50.
0
" The strength and effectiveness of this lobby is demonstrated by the response to
regulations proposed to permit deemed status for JCAH accredited nursing homes. A position
statement opposing use of JCAH accreditation for Medicare and Medicaid certification of the
National Citizens Coalition for Nursing Home Reform was endorsed by 43 national organiza-
tions (July 12, 1982). A letter to Secretary Schweicker expressing opposition to the bill was signed
by 49 Congressmen. A six month moratorium on the issuance of the regulations was passed by
Congress. The moratorium was subsequently extended 120 days.
See supra
note 64.
3
"
See supra
text accompanying notes 270-276.
3e]
& Arkin,
supra
note 361, at 749.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
887
In the recent past the federal government has explored this option with
regard to private standard-setting bodies generally. JCAH is, of course, not
the only private standard-setting and certifying body with considerable
authority over public decisions.
384
The implications of such power being held
by private bodies have not been lost on the federal government, which, during
the Carter Administration, showed real concern about the accountability of
private standard-setting bodies. A policy statement of the Office of Manage-
ment and Budget (OMB)
388
and proposed rules of the Federal Trade Commis-
sion (FTC)
386
issued in the late 1970's would have required considerable ex-
pansion of opportunities for public participation and public access to the stand-
ard making process.
387
Similar proposals were made by the National Standard
Policy Advisory Committee
388
and raised in Congress.
389
The Reagan Ad-
ministration has, however, distanced itself from these proposals, and given free
reign to private standard setting.
39
°
There are legal arguments under existing law for making JCAH function
like a public entity. First, there is the Administrative Procedures Act (APA).
39
'
The APA generally requires "agencies" of the federal government generally to
conduct public rule-making procedures,'" provide procedural protections to
subjects of formal adjudicatory decisions
393
and, with certain exceptions, hold
their records and determinations available for public inspection and
copying.'" If JCAH were deemed a federal agency, it essentially would have to
function like a public body and, in all likelihood, would be less efficient.
While the question is not wholly free from doubt, it seems unlikely that the
JCAH is an agency under the APA. In
Forsham
tr.
Harris,'" the Supreme Court
considered the definition of agency under the Freedom of Information Act
(FOIA) (which incorporates the definition of agency from the AP-A). Drawing
on an earlier case defining agency for tort claims act purposes,
396
and on
384
See
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, at 31-38.
3
" OMB Circular A-119, Federal Participation in the Development and Use of Volun-
tary Standards, 45 Fed. Reg. 4325 (1980);
but see
Proposed Revision of OMB Circular A-119, 47
Fed. Reg. 16,919 (1982).
"
6
See
Proposed Trade Regulation Rule — Standards and Certification, 43 Fed. Reg.
57,269 (1978)
(see
46 Fed. Reg. 39845 (1981), setting new schedule for submission of final staff
report) (to be codified at 16 C.F.R. 457).
3
" These proposals generally excluded from their coverage professional standardization
and certification,
see
47 Fed. Reg. 16920 (1982), 43 Fed. Reg. 57269 (1978), 45 Fed. Reg. 4326.
388
43 Fed. Reg. 6298 (1978).
389
See
Voluntary Standards Accreditation Act, 5.825, 95th Cong., 1st Sess. (1977).
399
See
47 Fed. Reg. 16,919 (1982).
391
5 U.S.C. 5 551-559 (1976 and Supp. IV, 1980).
392
5 U.S.C. 5 553 (1976). The rulemaking provisions do not apply to matters involving
loans, grants, benefits, or contracts and therefore might not cover much of the Medicare pro-
gram, JCAH's principal federal responsibility.
393
5 U.S.C. SS 554, 556, 557 (1976 and Supp. IV 1980).
3
"
5 U.S.C. S 552 (1976 and Supp. IV 1980).
3"
445 U.S. 169 (1980).
396
Id.
at 180 and note 11 citing United States v. Orleans, 425 U.S. 807 (1976).
888
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
legislative history of the FOIA showing that Congress did not intend to include
within the FOIA corporations that merely received grants from the federal
governmenf,
597
the Court held that absent "extensive, detailed, and virtually
day-to-day supervision,''
3
” grantees of the federal government do not become
agencies.
Although the JCAH receives large sums of money from the federal
government through reimburseable survey fees and is actively cooperating with
the federal government by providing information as to hospital accreditation, a
recent case —
Cospito
v.
Califano
399
has held that JCAH is not sufficiently
subject to day-to-day control by the federal government to make it an agency
under this test. The Court rejected the argument of the plaintiffs in
Cospito
(pa-
tients in a mental hospital who had lost federal assistance because JCAH had
disaccredited their facility) that JCAH was a federal agency subject to the
APA.
40
°
A stronger argument can be made for JCAH agency status under another
test that also appears in earlier cases and has not explicitly been rejected by the
Supreme Court. Under this test the question is whether an entity has independ-
ent "authority by law" to take "final and binding action affecting the rights
and obligations of individuals."
40
' Even under the independent authority test,
however, JCAH would probably not be subject to the APA and FOIA, as deci-
sions of the JCAH are in most instances not final independent government
decisions. Only in two instances does JCAH exercise authority that might sub-
ject it to the federal APA and FOIA under the independent authority test. The
first involves JCAH certification decisions concerning Medicaid payments to
psychiatric hospitals for minors; the second, certification decisions for Med-
icare or Medicaid payments to psychiatric hospitals not eligible for distinct
part certification. In both situations JCAH accreditation is required for pro-
gram participation
.
4
°
2
It should be noted, however, that the extensive authority
397
Forsham v. Harris, 445 U.S. at 179-80.
3
" Id. See also
Public Citizen Health Research Group v. Department of Health Educa-
tion and Welfare, 668 F.2d 537 (D,C. Cir. 1981); St. Michael's Convalescence Hosp. v. Califor-
nia, 643 F.2d 1369 (9th Cir. 1981); Irwin Memorial Blood Bank of the San Francisco Medical
Soc'y v. American Nat'l Red Cross, 640 F.2d 1051 (9th Cir. 1981) (applying a similar test).
2
" No. 77-859, at 23-25 (D.C. N.J. 1983) (granting JCAH motion for summary judg-
ment as Agency issue).
4
°°
Id.
at 23.
4
°' Lumbardo v. Handler, 397
F.
Supp. 792, 795 (D.D.C. 1975), aff'd 546 F,2d 1043
(D.C. Cir. 1976),
cert. denied,
431 U.S. 932 (1977) (quoting Freedman,
Administrative Procedure and
the Control of Foreign Direct Investments,
119 U. PA. L. REV. 1, 9 (1970)).
See also
Washington
Research Project Inc. v. DHEW, 504 F.2d 238, 248 (D.C. Cir. 1974)
cert. denied,
421 U.S. 963
(1975); Gruman Aircraft Eng'g Corp. v. Renegotiation Bd., 482 F.2d 710, 714, 715 (D.C. Cir.
1974)
rev'd on other grounds,
421 U.S. 168 (1975); Soucie v. David, 448 F,2d 1067, 1073 (D.C. Cir.
1971); Wolfe v. Weinberger, 403 F. Supp. 238, 241 (D.D.C. 1975); Note,
The Definition of
"Agency" Under the Freedom of Information Act as Applied to Federal Consultants and Grantees,
69 GEO.
L.J. 1223
(1981) (applying a similar test).
4
°
2
42 U.S.C.
1395x(f)(5) (1970).
See supra
note 61.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
889
given JCAH by law or regulation in some states may subject JCAH to some
state APA's or FOIA's.
403
A second potential legal tool
,
for increasing public control over JCAH is
the Federal Advisory Committees Act (ACA).
404
If JCAH were an advisory
committee under the ACA it would have to hold open meetings, publish notice
of its meetings in the Federal Register, make its records available to the public,
keep detailed minutes, and generally function subject to public oversight.
4
°
8
Section three of the Advisory Committees Act defines advisory committee to
mean:
any committee, board, commission, council, conference, panel, task force,
or other similar group, or any subcommittee or subgroup thereof . . . which
is (C) established or utilized by one or more agencies, in the interest of
obtaining advice or recommendations for the President or one or more agen-
cies or officers of the Federal Government ....
406
Insofar as JCAH is a "commission" utilized by HHS in the interest of obtain-
ing recommendations with regard to facilities that should be permitted to parti-
cipate in the federal Medicare program, it is arguably covered by this defini-
tion."'
This argument, however, does not hold up to more thorough analysis.
The ACA does not extend to entities that merely provide to the government
consultant services under contractual relationships
408
or to industry associa-
tions that voluntarily provide the government with proposals for regulatory ac-
tion.
409
Further, legislative history of the ACA establishes that the drafters in-
tended to exclude from ACA coverage committees or commissions with actual
responsibilities for program operations (like facility inspections).
410
The ACA
would, therefore, not seem to apply to entities such as the JCAH that have a
40
' See
Nassau-Suffolk Hosp. Council v. Whalen, 89 Misc.2d 304, 390 N.Y.S. 995
(1977) (holding JCAH reports delivered to Department of Health without a promise of con-
fidende are publicly available); Patients of Philadelphia State Hosp. v. Commonwealth of Pa., 53
Pa. Commw. 126, 417 A.2d 805 (1980) (holding JCAH report on state hospital to be public
record under state Right-to-Know act).
404
5 U.S.C. App. 1 (1976 and Supp. IV, 1980).
"
5
See
5 U.S.C. App. 1 5 10 (1976),
see
National Nutritional Food Ass'n v. Califano,
603 F.2d 327 (2d Cir. 1979); Food Chemical News Inc. v. Davis, 378 F. Supp. 1048 (D.D.C.
1974).
406
5 U.S.C. App. 1 § 3 (1976).
4
°
7
The possibility of the ACA applying to standard setting bodies has been recognized
by the commentators:
AD1vIINISTRATIVE CONFERENCE OF THE UNITED STATES, 1978
Report, p.
44 (1979); P.
HARTER,
supra
note
223, at 236-41; Hamilton, supra note 221, at 1475-77.
See also
Proposed Amendment to OMB-circular A-119, 47 Fed. Reg. 16,919, at 16,921 (1982) (noting
that standard setting bodies may be subject to the A.C.A. in some circumstances).
408
Lumbardo v. Handler, 397 F. Supp. 792, 799-800 (D.D.C. 1975); H.R. Rep.
No.
1017, 92nd Cong., 2d Sess. (1972)
reprinted
is 1972 U.S. CODE CONG. & AD. NEWS, at 3494
(House report supporting this conclusion).
409
Consumers Union of United States, Inc. v. HEW, 409 F. Supp. 473, 476-77
(D.D.C. 1976).
410
H.R. Rep. No. 1017, 92d Cong., 2d Sess. (1972)
reprinted in
1972 U.S. CODE CONG.
& AD. NEWS, at 3494.
890
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
IV ol.
24:835
substantial existence independent of the federal government and that carry on
their own programs in conjunction with and under contract to the federal
government.
Even if JCAH is neither an agency as defined in the APA or
FOIA
nor an
advisory committee as defined in the ACA, it may still be an instrumentality of
the federal or state governments for purposes of the application of the due proc-
ess provisions of the fifth and fourteenth amendments. The procedural protec-
tions of the Constitution limit only the actions of the government and not of
private entities. Nevertheless, it is often hard to determine whether the
acts
of
an entity that in some way is exercising or directing the power of the federal or
state government are "state action" subject to the control of the Constitution.*"
*" The Supreme Court has increasingly narrowed the scope of the state action doctrine
in recent years. Two cases decided by the court in its 1981 term, Blum v. Yaretsky, 102 S. Ct.
2777 (1982) and Rendell-Baker v. Kahn, 102 S. Ct. 2764 (1982) establish that the mere facts that
an entity, nominally private, receives virtually all of its funds from the government through a
contractual relationship, and is extensively subject to government regulation, do not make the
actions of the entity "fairly attributable to the state" for the purpose of applying the Fourteenth
Amendment unless the state has exercised coercive power or has provided such significant en-
couragement, either overt or covert, that the choice [motivating the private action] must in law
be deemed to be that of the State," 102 S. Ct. at 2786, or the private entity has exercised powers
that are "traditionally the exclusive prerogative of the state," 102 S. Ct. at 2786. Since few
JCAH decisions result from government compulsion and health care standardization and ac-
creditation are not traditional government functions,
Blum
and
Rendell-Baker
would not make
JCAH actions state actions.
In Lugar v. Edmonson Oil Co., 102 S. Ct. 2744 (1982), a third case decided on the same
day as
Mum
and
Rendell-Baker,
a nominally private party again was involved, specifically a
creditor that had seized property under a pre-judgment attachment procedure executed by the
county sheriff. 102 S. Ct. at 2747, 2748. The question in
Lugar
was whether the private use of a
state procedure in cooperation with a state officer was "under the color of state law" and thus
subject to the civil rights law, and ultimately to the Fourteenth Amendment. 102 S. Ct. at 2747,
2748. In this situation the court set out a different test: where there is a deprivation of a federal
right, this deprivation may be fairly attributable to the state if two conditions are met. First, the
deprivation must be caused "by the exercise of some right or privilege created by the state or by a
rule of conduct imposed by the state or by a person for whom the state is responsible." 102 S. Ct.
at 2754. Second, "the party charged with the deprivation [must be] a person who may be fairly
said to be a state actor ... because he is a state official, because he has acted together with or has
obtained significant aid from state officials, or because his conduct is otherwise chargeable to the
state." 102 S. Ct. at 2754.
JCAH accreditation in some respects more closely resembles the private conduct in
Lugar
than that in
Rendell-Baker
and
Blum.
While the JCAH standards, pursuant to which ac-
creditation decisions are made, are in one sense private rules of action, they have also been
adopted explicitly by the federal government through the deemed status law. By deeming JCAH
accredited hospitals to be eligible for Medicare participation, the federal government has effec-
tively adopted JCAH standards as its own and then imposed them on hospitals through JCAH.
In this capacity JCAH is a person for whom the federal government is responsible. Under the
second branch of the
Lugar
test JCAH accreditation decisions are attributable to the federal
government because they are made by JCAH in concert with HHS, which accepts them for pur-
poses of making Medicare payments.
Cf.
Fitzgerald v. Mountain Laurel Racing Inc., 607 F.2d
589, 598 (3rd Cir. 1979) (holding action of a race track suspending driver and approved by racing
official exercising delegated state power to be state action);
lnd cf.
Northrip v. FNMA, 527 F.2d
23, 30-33 (6th Cir. 1975) (holding involvement of FNMA with federal government does not
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
891
Whether or not JCAH is sufficiently a surrogate for the state or federal
government to subject it to the Constitution may rarely be of substantial conse-
quence. If hospitals are denied certification by JCAH they are protected by in-
ternal JCAH procedures that are at least as extensive as those minimally re-
quired by due process:
42
Fair review procedures for such denials may be re-
quired independent of the Constitution by general private organization law in
many states.
413
If, on the other hand, hospitals are improperly granted accredi-
tation and consumers or hospital employees and staff seek review, a substantial
barrier to review that in all likelihood will keep courts from reaching questions
of due process challenges will be raised by the lack of a casual relationship be-
tween the decision of JCAH and any injury to the employees or patients.
4
'
4
Thus due process as to JCAH quasi-judicial decisionmaking may seldom arise.
Only if the now nascent (or aborted) trend towards imposing due process re-
quirements on quasi-legislative rulemaking
4
" were to be considerably expand-
ed might due process obligations of JCAH become important. This seems
unlikely.
Even if a legal theory could be found for turning JCAH into a public enti-
ty, it is not wholly clear that this would radically improve the performance of
JCAH. While it might make JCAH more available for pursuing public policy
goals and more sensitive to consumer preferences and utility, it might also
make hospitals and physicians less cooperative with JCAH regulation. As
render its decisions not compelled by federal laws to be federal action). A similar analysis can be
applied to the JCAH role in some state licensure programs. Thus the intimate involvement of the
JCAH in administering federal or state government responsibilities might bring its actions within
the purview of the Fifth or Fourteenth Amendments.
See
Howard v. NCAA, 510 F.2d 213 (D.C.
Cir. 1975); Intercontinental Indus. v. American Stock Exchange, 452 F.2d 935 (5th Cir. 1971),
cert. denied,
409 U.S. 842; Stanley v. Big Eight Conference, 463 F. Supp. 920 (W.D. Mo. 1976);
Golden Rule Life Ins. v. Mathias, 86 Ill. App. 3d 323, 408 N.E.2d 310 (4th Dist. 1980).
The issue is, however, close and subject to debate. One case that has considered the
nature of JCAH has assumed in dicta that JCAH has acquired the character of a government ac-
tor. Sokol v. University Hosp. Inc., 402 F. Supp. 1029, 1031 (D. Mass. 1975). In a second case,
a motion to dismiss claiming JCAH was not a state actor was denied, Cospito v. Califano, 89
F.R.D. 374, 381, 382 (D. N.J. 1981). Subsequently, defendant's motion for summaryjudgment
was also denied, Cospito v. Califano, No. 77-869 at 22-23 (D. N.J. 1983). Finally, another case,
by contrast, identified JCAH as a private entity — though the question of JCAH state action was
not at issue. Slakoff v. Harrisburg Polyclinic Hosp., 375 F. Supp. 999, 1001, 1004 (M.D. Pa.
1974).
412
See
AMH,
supra
note 39, App. B, at 199-206.
4'3
Duby v. American College of Surgeons, 468 F.2d 364 (7th Cir. 1972); Pinsker v.
Pacific Coast Soc'y of Orthodontists, 12 Cal. 3d 541, 116 Cal. Rptr. 245, 526 P.2d 253 (1974);
Falcone v. Middlesex Co. Medical Soc., 34 N.J. 582, 170 A.2d 791 (1961).
414 See
O'Bannon v. Town Court Nursing Center, 441 U.S. 904 (1980). Under some
unusual circumstances it may, however, be possible to show causality.
See
Cospito v. Califano, 89
F.R.D. 374 (D. N.J. 1981) where JCAH disaccreditation of a psychiatric hospital led directly to
loss of federal benefits by the patients of the hospital.
4'S
Gellhorn & Robinson,
Rulernaking "Due Process": An Inconclusive Dialogue,
48 U.
CHI. L. REV.
201 (1981); Comment,
Due Process Rights of Participation in Administrative Rulemaking,
63
CALIF. L. REV.
886 (1975).
892
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
pointed out earlier,
46
JCAH can regulate efficiently because of its respon-
siveness to its constituency. To the extent the JCAH became a government
agency, it would in all likelihood function like a government agency, with
similar inefficiencies."' If the traditional constituencies of JCAH struggled to
retain control, it might become even less efficient and accountable than a
public agency. Salvation does not appear to lie this way.
V. SUPPLEMENTATION AND CONTROL OF JCAH
A final alternative is supplementation and control of JCAH. If JCAH is
anticompetitive it ought to be reined in through the antitrust laws. Insofar as it
exercises government power, it ought to be controlled and supplemented by the
government.
A.
Control of Anticompetitive Conduct Through the Antitrust Law
The public policy of the United States favors free-market competition and
opposes unreasonable restraints on trade. This policy is articulated in sections
one and two of the Sherman Antitrust Act.'" Section one forbids "(e)very con-
tract, combination in the form of a trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in re-
straint of trade or commerce among the several states, or with foreign
nations."" Section one is aimed at concerted activity — activity by two or
more persons or entities — that makes a market function less efficiently, usual-
ly by impeding competition. Section two deems it illegal for any person to
"monopolize or attempt to monopolize or combine or conspire with any person
or persons to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several
states, or with foreign nations . "
4
" Section two is narrower than section
one in that it focuses on one particular kind of anticompetitive conduct,
monopolization, but is also of potentially broader application in that a single
person or entity can violate section two. As will be developed further below, in-
sofar as JCAH in concert with other persons or organizations impedes competi-
tion in the markets for physician, hospital or other medical services, it may
violate section one. Insofar as it monopolizes the market for accreditation serv-
ices, it may violate section two.
1. Antitrust: Preliminary Considerations
Before applying substantive antitrust law to JCAH it is first necessary to
consider antitrust jurisdictional requirements and antitrust defenses that might
exempt JCAH activities from scrutiny under the Sherman Act. These defenses
and immunities traditionally have precluded or severely limited application of
416
supra
text accompanying notes 358-60.
417
See supra
text accompanying and authorities cited at note 373.
419
U.S.C. SS 1, 2 (1976).
419
15 U.S.C.
S
1 (1976).
420
15 U.S.C.
5
2 (1976).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
893
the antitrust laws in the health care context. To the extent that they retain their
former vitality, they may limit the usefulness of the antitrust laws in controlling
JCAH.
Establishing Sherman Act jurisdiction over JCAH should not be difficult.
First, JCAH's restraints on trade must be shown to affect interstate or foreign
commerce. The most frequent context in which antitrust challenges to JCAH
standards are mounted is denial of hospital staff privileges. Until the mid-
1970's, courts routinely dismissed antitrust challenges to denials of hospital
staff privileges, holding that such denials had no effect on interstate
commerce."' In 1976, however, the Supreme Court in
Hospital Building Com-
pany v. Trustees of Rex Hospital
422
liberally construed the interstate commerce re-
quirement as applied to hospitals, deciding that the interstate purchase of med-
ical supplies, receipt of insurance reimbursement, payment of management
fees, and arrangement of finance contracts provided sufficient interstate con-
tacts to ground an antitrust claim concerning the blocked expansion of a
hospital."'
The Court further limited the rigor of the interstate commerce require-
ment in
McLain v. Real Estate Board of New Orleans,
Inc. ,
424
which held that a
plaintiff need only show that a defendant's total activities have a substantial ef-
fect on interstate commerce, and need not show that a particular alleged viola-
tion will itself affect interstate commerce.
425
Recent antitrust cases concerning
hospital staff privileges have readily found interstate commerce jurisdiction.
425
If an antitrust action is brought directly challenging the anticompetitive
effects of a JCAH decision to refuse accreditation to a facility or class of facili-
ties — as opposed to a challenge to a JCAH standard — interstate commerce
jurisdiction may be found even more easily. Denial of JCAH accreditation to
the facility is likely to have, in itself, a significant effect on interstate
commerce.
427
421
See, e.g. ,
Wolf v. Jane Phillips Episcopal-Memorial Medical Center, 513 F.2d 684,
687, (10th Cir. 1975); Spears Free Clinic and Hosp. for Poor Children v. Cleere, 197 F.2d 125,
128 (10th Cir. 1952).
422
425 U.S.C. 738 (1976).
423
Id.
at 744.
424
444 U.S.C. 232 (1980).
422
Id.
at 242, 243.
426
See, e.g.,
Mischler v. St. Anthony's Hosp. Sys., 1981-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) I] 64,342
(10th Cir. Nov. 2, 1981); Crane v. Intermountain Health Care, Inc., 637 F.2d 715, 721-27 (10th
Cir. 1981); Feminist Women's Health Center Inc. v. Mohammed, 586 F.2d 530, 539-41 (5th
Cir. 1978),
(ed. denied,
444 U.S. 924 (1979); McDonald v. St. Joseph's Hosp. of Atlanta, 524
F.
Supp. 122, 127-30 (N.D. Ga. 1981); Robinson v. McGovern, 521
F.
Supp. 842, 876-77 (W.D.
Pa. 1981); Malini v. Singleton & Assoc's., 516
F.
Supp. 440, 441-45 (S.D. Tex. 1981); Feldman
v. Jackson Memorial Hosp., 509 F. Supp. 815, 820, 821 (S.D. Fla. 1981); Denver v. Santa Bar-
bara Community Dialysis Center, 1981-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) i 63,946 (C.D. Cal. Feb. 26,
1981); Zamiri v. William Beaumont Hosp., 430 F. Supp. 875, 877 (E.D. Mich. 1977).
Contra
Capili v. Shott, 620 F.2d 438, 439 (4th Cir. 1980).
422
See also
Boddicker v. Arizona State Dental Ass'n, 549 F.2d 626, 629 (9th Cir. 1977)
(holding denial of membership in a national association may itself affect interstate commerce);
894
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
Until less than a decade ago JCAH might have raised a second jurisdic-
tional barrier, arguing that professional, non-commercial activities were ex-
cluded from the coverage of the antitrust laws. Dicta in earlier Supreme Court
cases had left open the distinct possibility that professional self-regulatory ac-
tivities, even activities that intentionally restrained competition, were not sub-
ject to scrutiny under the antitrust laws, which, after all, applied only to trade
and commerce:
42
s An antitrust exemption for professional services was rejected
by the Supreme Court, however, in a series of cases beginning with
Goldfarb v.
The Virginia State Bar
429
in 1975. Following
Goldfarb,
a court has recently rejected
the professional exemption defense in a case challenging JCAH standards
limiting access of chiropractors to hospitals when the defense was raised by
the AMA and other codefendants.
4
" Other defenses, however, are more
troublesome.
a.
Antitrust
Law and Freedom of Communication
Activity which would otherwise be proscribed by the Sherman Act may be
protected from antitrust sanctions by two doctrines developed in response to
first amendment concerns. The first doctrine protects certain concerted ac-
tivities intended to influence governmental action. The second protects com-
mercial speech.
In opposing antitrust challenges to its program, JCAH has argued that the
procompetitive policy of the antitrust law must be subordinated to the constitu-
tional policy protecting freedom of petition and expression."' Reconciliation of
the antitrust laws with the first amendment has been accomplished traditional-
ly through the
Noerr-Pennington
doctrine, developed by the Supreme Court in a
series of cases in the early 1960'5.
432
Noerr-Pennington
protects from antitrust
sanctions concerted attempts to influence public political opinion or legislative,
but see
Nara v. American Dental Ass'n, 526 F. Supp. 452, 455-57 (W.D. Wis. 1981) (finding no
effect on interstate commerce where dentist denied membership in A.D.A.).
428
See
United States v. Oregon State Medical Soc., 343 U.S. 326, 336 (1952); American
Medical Ass'n v. United States, 317 U.S. 519, 528 (1943).
See also
Marjorie Webster JuniOr Col-
lege Inc. v. Middle States Ass'n of Colleges and Secondary Schools, Inc., 432 F.2d 650, 653-655
(D.C. Cir. 1970)
cert. denied,
400 U.S. 965 (1970) (holding an educational accrediting association
exempt from the antitrust laws).
429
421 U.S. 773, 786-88 (1975).
See also
Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc'y,
102 S. Ct. 2466, 2465-2478 (1982); National Soc'y of Prof. Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S.
679, 696 (1978). State antitrust laws, on the other hand, frequently do not apply to professional
activities:
see
Mohammed, 586 F.2d at 552, 553; Moles v. White, 336 So.2d 427, 429-30 (Fla.
Dist. Ct. App. 1976),
cert. dismissed,
355 So.2d 516 (Fla, 1978); People v. Roth, 52 N.Y.2d 440,
447-48, 420 N.E.2d 929, 930 (1981).
4
'
6
Health Care Equalization Comm. of the Iowa Chiropractic Soc'y v. Iowa Medical
Soc'y, No. 79-381-A943-6 (order Feb. 12, 1982) (earlier order at 501 F. Supp. 970).
4
"
See id.
at 12-13 (refusing to strike first amendment defense at pleading stage).
492
See
United Mine Workers of Am. v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657, 669-71 (1965);
Eastern R.R. Presidents Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight Inc., 365 U.S. 127, 137-38 (1961);
see also
Cal. Motor Transp. Co. v. Trucking Unlimited, 404 U.S. 508, 513-15 (1972) (applying the
Noerr-Pennington doctrine to a case where plaintiffs challenged defendant's allegedly anticom-
petitive use of administrative
.
agencies and the courts).
July 19831
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
895
executive, or judicial decision-makers, even if the efforts are meant to achieve
an anticompetitive result.
433
The
Noerr-Pennington
doctrine is based not only on
the first amendment but also on congressional intent that the antitrust laws not
constrain political advocacy.
434
The
Noerr-Pennington
doctrine is subject to an important exception, the
"sham" exception: "there may be situations in which a publicity campaign,
ostensibly directed towards influencing government action, is a mere sham to
cover what is actually nothing more than an attempt to interfere directly with
the business relationshlp of the competitor and the application of the Sherman
Act would be justified."
4
" In many cases extended consideration of the true
nature of concerted anticompetitive activities that resemble political advocacy
is necessary to determine whether they are protected by
Noerr-Pennington
or fall
within the sham exception.
The second defense stemming from the first amendment and limiting an-
titrust sanctions arises from recent Supreme Court cases limiting application of
the antitrust laws to commercial speech.
Virginia State Board of Pharmacy v.
Virginia Consumers Council
hic.,
436
a case considering statutory limitations on
drug advertising, held that the first amendment protects commercial speech,
defined as speech that does "no more than propose a commercial trans-
action."
437
A series of subsequent cases have further clarified the perimet-
ers of "commercial speech" and the extent to which it is subject to goverment
regulation.'"
Metro-Media Inc. a. City of San Diego,
139
a 1981 Supreme Court
case, set out a four point test for determining the permissibility of government
restrictions on commercial speech:
(1) The First Amendment protects commercial speech only if that speech
concerns lawful activity and is not misleading. A restriction on otherwise
protected commercial speech is valid only if it (2) seeks to implement a
substantial governmental interest, (3) directly advances that interest, and (4)
reaches no further than necessary to accomplish the given objective.
440
Although the first amendment
protections of commercial speech have not
yet been applied in the antitrust area, commentators have argued that com-
mercial speech doctrine should be applied broadly to protect medical accredita-
tion and standardization programs from antitrust scrutiny.
441
This is an un-
4
" See Noerr,
365 U.S. 135-38.
434
Id.
at 137, 138.
"' Id.
at
144.
See also
California Motor Transp., 404 U.S. at 511-16 (further elaborating
on the "sham" exception).
136
425 U.S. 748 (1976).
17
Id.
at 762 (citing Pittsburgh Press Co. v. Human Relations Comm'n., 413 U.S. 376,
385 (1973).
4
" Metromedia Inc. v. City of San Diego, 453 U.S. 490, 498-521 (1981); Central Hud-
son Gas & Elec. v. Public Serv. Comm'n, 447 U.S. 557, 563-66 (1980) (setting out four-part
test).
4
" 453 U.S. 490 (1981).
44
°
Id.
at
507, citing
Central Hudson,
447
U.S. at 563-66.
441
See
Kissam,
supra
note 284, at 677-80; Kissam,
Applying Antitrust Law to Medical
896
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
warranted extension of the commercial speech doctrine.
Virginia Pharmacy
and
its progeny explicitly protect only advertising, one of the many forms of non-
political speech "of an entirely private and economic character.
,,
442
C
om
-munication
intended to facilitate anticompetitive coordination among. pro-
ducers occupying parallel positions in a production chain differs in significant
respects from advertising, i.e., communication between ultimate buyers and
sellers .
445
The Court based its decision in
Virginia Pharmacy
in part on the postulate
that society has a strong interest in free exchanges of information regarding
products and prices to preserve the free enterprise system and to assure proper
allocation of resources.*** Exchanges of information between coordinate sellers
could, in contrast to advertising directed at consumers, hamper the efficient
allocation of resources and threaten the free enterprise system.
445
Even speech
ostensibly directed at consumers might do more harm than good to the market
if its real purpose and effect were to coordinate anticompetitive activities.
446
Ac-
cordingly, antitrust law has long limited certain kinds of information ex-
changes, recognizing that the free exchange of information must bow to en-
forcement of the antitrust law where communication has been used to hamper
competition.
447
This is not to say that communication between competitors is not entitled
to some protection. Indeed, antitrust law has traditionally recognized the
beneficial aspects of dissemination and exchange of information.
448
But just as
first amendment doctrine concerning advertising has developed independently
of the law of political speech, with its own exceptions and subject to its own
unique balancing test,
449
so the law of communication between competitors has
Credentialing, 7
AM. J.
OF L. &
MED.
1, 18-25 (1981); Kissam,
Antitrust Law, the First Amendment,
and Professional Self-Regulation of Technical Quality,
in REGULATING THE PROFESSIONS,
supra
note
277, at 143 (hereinafter cited as Kissam,
First Amendment). See also W.
Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at
III 94-111 97 (discussing Kissana's commercial speech argument).
442
See
425 U.S. 763, n.17. For a comparison of the commercial speech doctrine with
first amendment doctrine as it,has developed in regard to another kind of economic speech,
see
Note,
Labor Picketing and Commercial Speech,
91 YALE L.J. 938 (1982).
"3
W. Lazarus,
supra note 72, at III 95-111 96.
"4
425 U.S. at 762-65.
44
' W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at III 95-111 96.
446
Id.
447
National Soc'y of Professional Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 697 (1978);
United States v. Container Corp. of Am., 393 U.S. 333, 337 (1969); American Column and
Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. 377, 392, 412 (1921); American Medical Ass'n
v.
F.T.C., 638 F.2d 443, 451, 452 (2d Cir. 1980).
448.
This is especially true as to information exchanges through standardization pro-
grams,
see
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
supra
note 223, at 39-54, 86-87; C.
LAMB & C.
SHIELDS,
supra
note 298, at 78-80, 90, 95.
Cf. M.
POLLARD & R. LIEBENLUFT, ANTITRUST AND
THE HEALTH PROFESSIONS 34-37 (1981); Liebenluft & Pollard,
Antitrust Scrutiny
of
the Health Pro-
fessions: Developing a Framework for Assessing Private Restraints,
34
VAND.
L. REV. 927, 947-949
(1981) (discussing procompetitive effects of health care standardization).
449
See supra
text accompanying note 440.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
897
developed and ought to continue to develop independent of the law of commer-
cial speech, subject to its own exceptions and its own balancing test. Specifical-
ly, if communication between competitors is intended to exclude coercively
other competitors from a market, it ought not to be protected speech.
45
°
The effect of the first amendment limitations on antitrust controls over
certification and standardization programs must, to a large extent, depend on
the nature of those programs. If standardization or certification programs are
accurately characterized as petitions for political action, as might be the case if
a trade association developed standards explicitly for government regulation or
advocated government adoption of its certification or accreditation program,
such programs may be protected by the
Noerr-Pennington
rule. If, on the other
hand, a standardization or certification program is aimed primarily at facilitat-
ing purchasing decisions by consumers, as may be true of the Good House-
keeping Seal of Approval, the program may be protected by the commercial
speech exception.
The analysis presented earlier in this article,
451
however, shows that the
JCAH standardization and accreditation programs are not aimed at ultimate
consumers of health care. Though JCAH does not conceal its standards from
the public, it has made few attempts to disseminate its standards to the public
or to educate the public as to the content of these standards."' Indeed, JCAH
officials have opined that the public has little ability to comprehend JCAH
standards
.
4
"
Neither are JCAH standards aimed at government. Although the federal
government and some state governments have in effect incorporated JCAH
standards into their regulations by granting deemed status for licensure or cer-
tification to JCAH accredited facilities, JCAH has not advocated government
adoption of its standards,
454
and indeed has self-consciously developed stand-
ards independent of government regulatory purposes.
455
JCAH standards are
only in the most attenuated sense advertising and are not significantly political
speech.
This is also true to a somewhat lesser extent of the JCAH accreditation
program. Although a list of accredited facilities is publicly available, JCAH
makes no effort to publicize this information.
456
Moreover, it is militantly pro-
+
5
° Although I am unaware of cases in which courts have squarely addressed this ques-
tion, there is no reason why the approach that courts have taken to communications between
competitors in other antitrust contexts
(see supra
at note 447) ought not to apply here.
15
' See supra
Section II.
452
The
ACCREDITATION MANUAL FOR
HOSPITALS,
for example, is only available from
the JCAH Chicago office at a cost of $20.00.
"' See
Lewis,
The Uncertain Future ofJCAH,
4 MODERN HEALTH CARE, Aug. 1975 at 20,
21.
45+
supra
note 51, at 8; Schlicke,
supra
note 72, at 385.
455 See
authorities cited
supra note 54.
456
See Hearings, supra
note 54, at 1900 (testimony of J. Porterfield, Director of JCAH);
Affeldt,
Confidentiality, supra
note 353, at 44.
898
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
tective of the information on which its accreditation decisions are based.
4
"
Thus, JCAH accreditation programs should not be characterized as commer-
cial speech. Neither is it appropriate to characterize JCAH accreditation pro-
grams as petitions to government. JCAH does not affirmatively petition the
government to pay or to license accredited facilities; instead, when required by
statute, it merely informs the government of its decisions.
The main functions of the JCAH standardization and accreditation pro-
grams, according to the economic analysis developed earlier
458
are, first, to
enhance the acceptability of sellers of medical care services — hospitals and
other institutional medical care providers — and, second, to produce informa-
tion for the benefit of other medical care providers who are intermediate or
complementary producers of services — physicians or for other private enti-
ties with independent interests in the suitability of health care facilities — pro-
fessional associations.
459
This information may serve a useful societal function,
but it is no more political petitioning or commercial speech than was the data
dissemination held to be illegal in earlier trade association cases
45
° (or the price
information at issue in
Goldfarb).
If JCAH programs otherwise violate the anti-
trust laws, they ought not to be protected because they incidentally involve
communication.
b.
Antitrust Law and Federal Preemption
JCAH has also argued that its standardization and accreditation program
is impliedly immune from federal antitrust scrutiny because of the role of
JCAH in the administration of the federal Medicare program."' Immunity
problems arise when antitrust laws come into conflict with other federal stat-
utes promoting other policies. The courts must then reconcile the conflict or ex-
plicitly choose one set of statutes and policies over the other.
Based on its Medicare role, JCAH can argue that: (1) the federal
Medicare law explicitly adopts JCAH standardization and accreditation,
thereby making JCAH a federal regulator, and immunizing JCAH from an-
titrust scrutiny; or (2) even if the Medicare law does not make JCAH a federal
regulator as such, it does compel JCAH to adopt and enforce anticompetitive
policies, again confering immunity. If JCAH is merely carrying out federal
policy, it would be unfair to punish JCAH for its anticompetitive effects.
National Gerimedical Hospital and Gerontology Center v. Blue Cross of Kansas
City,
462
is the most recent Supreme Court case considering antitrust immunity
457
See supra
text accompanying notes 353-54.
458
See supra
text accompanying notes 257-322.
459
See
authorities cited
supra
at notes 73-74.
46
°
See
cases cited
supra
note 447.
461
Memorandum of Defendant JCAH for Summary Judgment, at 10-37 (April 27,
1981); Reply Memorandum of Defendant JCAH in Support of Motion for Summary Judgment
(July 2, 1981) (hereinafter cited as Reply Memorandum); Ohio v. JCAH, No. C-2-79-1158
(S.D. Ohio filed Dec. 14, 1979).
#62
452 U.S. 378 (1981)._
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
899
based on implied exemption. The defendant Blue Cross, ostensibly to promote
the policies established by the National Health Planning and Resources
Development Act of 1974,
463
had refused to allow a hospital to participate in its
health insurance plan because the hospital had failed to obtain approval for
facility construction from the local Health Systems Agency (which was respon-
sible under the federal Health Planning Act for approving capital investment
by hospitals).
464
When the hospital sued under the antitrust law, Blue Cross
claimed that its decision was immune from antitrust scrutiny because the
Health Planning Act had impliedly repealed the antitrust laws as to its con-
duct.
463
In rejecting this contention, the Court stated that the antitrust law sets
out a fundamental national policy.
466
Under settled law on implied immunity
from the antitrust law, a party claiming exemption must show by convincing
evidence a clear repugnancy between the antitrust laws and a specific regula-
tory program.
467
According to the court, repeal will be implied only to the
minimum extent necessary to make the subsequent regulatory law work and
when clear congressional intent to repeal the antitrust laws is shown.
468
The
Supreme Court rejected the argument that extensive government regulation of
the health care industry in itself repealed the antitrust laws and held that the
National Health Planning Law was not so incompatible with the antitrust laws
as to repeal pervasively the Sherman Act.
469
The Court further held that as
Blue Cross' actions were not specifically compelled by the health planning law,
the mere fact that they were consistent with the policy of that Act did not pro-
tect them.
47
°
National Gerimedical
is relevant to both of JCAH's exemption arguments.
First, JCAH should not be able to claim that the incorporation of its standards
into federal law through the deeming process immunizes its standardization
and accreditation program from antitrust scrutiny.
National Gerimedical
noted,
"antitrust repeals are especially disfavored when the antitrust implications of
business decisions have not been considered by a governmental entity.
"471
Like the Blue Cross decision in
National Gerimedical,
JCAH standards are not
themselves specifically compelled by federal "regulatory coercion" but are in-
stead "governed in the first instance by business [or professional] judgment. "
472
463
42 U.S.C. $ 3001.. (1976 and Supp. III).
464
National Gerimedical,
452 U.S. at 381.
465
Id.
at 382.
466
Id.
at 388.
4
"
Id.
at 388. United States v. National Ass'n of Securities Dealers, 422 U.S. 694,
719-20 (1975); Gordon v. New York Stock Exchange, 422 U.S. 659, 682 (1975).
468
National Gerimedical,
452 U.S. at 389.
469
Id.
at 391-93.
47°
Id.
at 389-91.
See also
Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366, 374
(1973) (holding that Federal Power Commission regulation of power company did not immunize
the power company's actions from antitrust scrutiny if those actions were not coerced by the
FPC).
"' National Gerimedical,
452 U.S. at 390.
472
Id.
at 390, quoting
Otter Tail,
410 U.S. at 374.
900
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
Moreover, it is difficult to argue that Congress considered and adopted specific
JCAH standards by merely permitting hospitals "deemed status" for
Medicare participation based on JCAH accreditation.'"
Second,
National Gerimedical
may weaken JCAH's argument that insofar as I
its standards are consistent with federal requirements, those standards are im-
mune from antitrust sanctions. This argument is currently being litigated in
Ohio v. The Joint Commission on Accreditation of Hospitals,
a case brougheby the
State of Ohio claiming that JCAH has conspired with its member organiza-
tions in violation of the Sherman Act to keep psychologists from competing
with doctors."' Ohio has claimed that JCAH has excluded psychologists from
hospital practice through its standards.'" JCAH in defense has argued that its
restrictions on the hospital staff privileges of psychologists in psychiatric and
general hospitals are immune from antitrust scrutiny because they are consist-
ent with and authorized by the Medicare law's definitions of hospital and
psychiatric hospital and with federal regulations that require hospital care to be
supervised by a physician and define physician to include doctors but to ex-
clude psychologists.'"
Ohio has raised two responses to this argument. First, it has argued that
JCAH's hospital staffing standards are more restrictive than those of the
Medicare statute and regulations."' This argument seems weak: while the
Medicare definition of physician is for some purposes broader than that of
JCAH,"" the federal and JCAH standards as to psychologists are in fact very
similar.'"
The state's second argument is that the Medicare program is an insurance
program rather than a regulatory program and, therefore, neither the JCAH
473
Another parallel to the authority accorded the medical industry by the federal
government to regulate itself in the context of federal financing programs through JCAH is the
extensive self-regulatory authority granted the stock exchanges. In both instances the federal
government has abstained from exerting the full potential force of its regulatory power, deferring
instead to self-regulation. Yet, the courts have held that statutes permitting self-regulation of the
stock exchanges do not immunize anticompetitive conduct of the stock exchanges from the an-
titrust laws. Silver v. New York Stock Exchange, 373 U.S. 341, 357-61 (1963);
Otter Tail,
410
U.S. 366, 372-375 (1973); California v. FPC, 369 U.S. 482, 485-90 (1962); United States v.
Radio Corp. of Am., 358 U.S. 334, 346-53 (1959).
474
No. C-2-79-1138 (S.D. Ohio filed Dec. 14, 1979).
473
See
Plaintiff's Memorandum in Opposition to Defendant's Motion for Summary
Judgment ( June 5, 1981), at 1-5 in Ohio v. JCAH, civ. No. 3-2-79-1158 (S.D. Ohio filed) (here-
inafter cited as Plaintiff's Memorandum).
4
" See
authorities cited
supra
note 461.
4
"
See
Plaintiff's Memorandum,
supra note 475, at 9-13.
478
Compare the definition of physician in 42 U.S.C. $ 1395x(r) (1976) and 42 C.F.R.
405.232a (1982) (including chiropractors, optometrists, podiatrists, dentists, physicians, and
osteopaths for some purposes) with the JCAH definition of physician, AMH,
supra
note 39, at
209 (including only medical doctors and osteopaths). 42 U.S.C. 5 1395x(e)(1) & (4) (1976) re-
quires that all patients in Medicare certified hospitals be under the supervision of a physician.
479
Psychologists are not defined as physicians under the federal Medicare law;
see id.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
901
nor the hospitals are required to comply with Medicare conditions of participa-
tion.
48
° The state draws support for its second argument from
National Society of
Professional Engineers v. United States."' ,..The
Court held in
Professional Engineers
that just because the federal government as a purchaser may choose not to pur-
sue a competitive purchasing policy, a combination of sellers of services is not
thereby justified in pursuing an identical policy against competitive bidding.
482
The state has argued, similarly, that just because the Medicare program has
chosen to purchase services from certain kinds of providers, JCAH standards
favoring those same providers by suppressing competition from others are not
thereby permissible. JCAH has attached private consequences to government-
al policies, the potential effects of which go beyond the immediate consequen-
ces of governmental actions, just as Blue Cross did in
National Gerimedical.
JCAH
has stressed in response that as a practical matter virtually all hos-
pitals participate in the Medicare program, and most hospitals are forced to do
so economically, if not legally."' JCAH's argument here makes sense. Even
though neither JCAH nor the hospitals are legally compelled to comply with
anticompetitive Medicare standards, it is difficult to argue that anticompetitive
results of compliance with both JCAH and federal standards are proximately
caused by JCAH anticompetitive policies. Hence, JCAH may be able to de-
fend itself from antitrust claims where its standards parallel federal law — as
they seem to with regard to psychologists. Where JCAH standards are more re-
strictive of competition than is federal law, on the other hand, the status of ac-
creditation in the Medicare program ought not alone to be enough to protect
JCAH from antitrust scrutiny.
c. Antitrust Law and State Regulation
A final defense to antitrust complaints relevant to JCAH is the state action
exemption first articulated in and thus identified with,
Parker v, Brown.
484
Un-
der this exception, the courts have, in reliance on considerations of federalism,
statutory construction
485
and fairness to persons caught between the Syclla of
federal antitrust law and the Charybdis of state regulation, excused state re-
quired concerted anticompetitive actions from antitrust sanctions. JCAH could
argue that the
Parker Brown
exception immunized JCAH policies from antitrust
scrutiny in those states where JCAH accreditation plays a major role in licens-
ure decisions.
The state action exception, however, has been interpreted very
narrowly.
486
For private action to be immune from antitrust scrutiny, it must
480
Plaintiff's Memorandum,
supra
note 475, at 6-9.
481
435 U.S. 679, at 694 n.21 (1978).
See
Plaintiff's Memorandum,
supra
note 475, at
7-8.
482
Id,
483
Reply Memorandum,
supra
note 461, at 13.
4
" 317 U.S. 341, 351-52 (1943).
483
Congress did not intend the antitrust laws to preempt state regulatory policies.
Id.
486
See
Community Communications Co. v. City of Boulder, 102 S. Ct. 835, 841-44
902
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
not only be compelled by state law but also be actively supervised by state
regulation."' Mere state reliance on JCAH standards and accreditation deci-
sions for licensing of health care institutions falls short of the state compulsion
and supervision standard, and thus would not exempt JCAH from antitrust
scrutiny.
488
Indeed, absent state regulatory oversight JCAH may not be pro-
tected even in pursuing legislatively articulated state policies.
469
Questions of
JCAH causation of anticompetitive effects, however, may arise in specific cases
when JCAH standards parallel state regulations. For example, if a state licens-
ing law forbids psychologists hospital admitting privileges, a psychologist can
hardly blame JCAH for a hospital's refusal of such privilege. But the state ac-
tion exemption itself is unlikely to prove an effective shield for anticompetitive
JCAH accreditation and standardization activities.
In summary, the defenses discussed above — the
Noerr-Pennington
doc-
trine, the commercial speech doctrine, federal preemption, and the state action
exemption — seem unlikely to protect JCAH activities from scrutiny under an-
titrust law to any significant extent. Thus, if JCAH activities violate antitrust
law, that law can be used to control the anticompetitive aspects of JCAH pro-
grams.
2. JCAH Restraints of Trade
Two elements are necessary to establish a violation of section one of the
Sherman Act. First, concerted activity must be shown. Second, it must be
established that such activity unreasonably restrains trade.
a.
Proof of Concerted Activities
To establish a violation of section one of the Sherman Act the plaintiff
must first show the existence of an agreement between two or more persons.
4
"
It is not enough to show that the actions of one, or even several entities, acting
individually pursuing their independent interests are in fact anticompetitive.
An initial issue, therefore, is whether any anticompetitive effects of the JCAH
standardization or accreditation programs are the result of concerted activity.
The first and surest means of establishing the requisite concerted activity
is to show that the JCAH has in fact explicitly agreed with other persons or en-
tities to engage in anticompetitive conduct. It is not necessary, however, to
(1982); California Retail Liquor Dealers Ass'n v. Mid Cal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U.S. 97, 102-06
(1980); City of Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light Co., 435 U.S. 389, 394-97 (1978).
487
Mid Cal,
445 U.S. at 105.
488 Just as in
Mid
Cal, the state enforced private wine-pricing scheme was held invalid
because the prices were privately established and not reviewed by the state.
489
Id., but see
Kartell v. Blue Shield, 542 F. Supp. 782, 790 (D. Mass. 1982) (holding
legislation compelling a practice may make state supervision unnecessary).
4
"
See
15 U.S.C. 5 1 (1976); L. SULLIVAN, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW OF ANTITRUST
$ 108 (1977).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
903
prove the terms of an explicit written or oral agreement,*" an agreement can
be implied from the conduct of the parties. If the existence of an explicit or im-
plicit agreement must be established by circumstantial evidence, there are
several factors the courts generally find persuasive: the uniformity of the par-
ties' conduct; whether the parties had meetings or other opportunities to form
an agreement; whether the conduct is in the interests of the the parties if they
act together but against their individual interests acting independently;
whether any party has sacrificed its individual interests in reliance on a similar
sacrifice by other parties, and whether any party has sufficient coercive power
to compel another to give up its independent decision making,
492
Proof only of
uniformity of conduct is generally insufficient to establish an agreement.'"
Thus, the mere fact that several organizations have similar standards limiting
the economic competitiveness of non-physicians might not be enough to
establish an unlawful restraint of trade. Where uniformity is accompanied by
other conduct, however, an agreement may be inferred from all the cir-
cumstances. Thus, in
Wilk v. American Medical Association,
the plaintiffs set out
to prove to a jury by circumstantial evidence the existence of an agreement
betweeen the JCAH, AMA, Illinois Medical Society, ACS, American
Academy of Orthopedic Surgeons, American College of Radiology, and ACP
to boycott chiropractors through,
inter alia,
the imposition of JCAH
standards."
A second method for meeting the concerted action requirement would be
to allege and prove that the JCAH is in itself an unlawful combination. In
Virginia Academy of Clinical Psychologists v. Blue Shield of Virginia,
4
"
the court held
that the defendant, the Blue Shield Association of Virginia, in appearance a
discrete and independent corporation, was in fact a combination of par-
ticipating physicians who had conspired together through the Blue Shield to
boycott psychologists: "It is not sufficient to assert, as defendants do, that a
corporation cannot conspire with itself. We must look at substance rather than
form.
"195
In support of its analysis, the court cited
United States v. Sealy Inc."'
in
which the Supreme Court held that where a manufacturer was substantially
owned and controlled by its licensees, its action in allocating territories be-
491
See
L. SULLIVAN,
supra note 490, at
5
109.
492
See
Interstate Circuit Inc. v. United States, 306 U.S. 208, 227 (1939); C-0 Two Fire
Equip. Co. v. United States, 197 F.2d 489, 491-94 (9th Cir.)
cert. denied,
344 U.S. 892 (1952); L.
SULLIVAN,
supra
note 490, at S 110.
493
See
Theatre Enterprises v. Paramount Film Distributing Co., 346 U.S. 537, 541
(1954).
4
"
See
Preliminary Brief for Plaintiffs-Appellants at 11-52 (May 13, 1981); Wilk v.
AMA, No. 81-1331 (pending 7th Cir.) (hereinafter cited as Preliminary Brief).
495
624 F.2d 476 (4th Cir. 1980).
4
"
Id.
at 481.
497
388 U.S. 350 (1967).
See also
Marrese v. American Academy of Orthopedic
Surgeons, 496 F. Supp. 236, 240 (N.D. Ill. 1980) (enforcement of alleged anticompetitive by-law
through internal sanctions by an association of competitors sufficient to ground antitrust com-
plaint).
904
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
1Vol. 24:835
tween them was in fact a horizontal agreement between the licensee stock-
holders. Applying this analysis, a court could hold that the JCAH was in fact
an ongoing conspiracy between the AMA, AHA, ACS, ACP, and ADA, and
find any of its standards or accreditation decisions arrived at by a common vote
of the members to be concerted action in restraint of trade. Evidence that
JCAH commissioners voted as directed by member organizations would sup-
port this theory.
498
Finally, the agreement between a hospital and JCAH for a hospital to sub-
mit to JCAH standards, and for JCAH to accredit the hospital could be a suffi-
cient basis for finding an illegal combination if it resulted in the hospital taking
anticompetitive actions that it might not have taken independently.
Because so many independent entities act together in the JCAH standard-
ization and accreditation process, it will probably be possible in many instances
to show concerted action. It is therefore necessary to decide whether any
aspects of the JCAH program are unreasonable restraints on trade.
b.
Introduction to Substantive Analysis of Trade Restraints
Section one of the Sherman Act forbids all combinations in "restraint of
trade."
499
The courts recognized very early, however, that all contractual rela-
tionships to some extent restrain trade, and thus that the law cannot mean
what it seems to say.
5
" The Supreme Court, in the early case of
Chicago Board of
Trade v. United States,
set forth a distinction between reasonable and unreason-
able or undue restraints of trade which the courts continue to apply:
Every agreement concerning trade, every regulatidn of trade, restrains. To
bind, to restrain is of their
very
essence. The true
test
of legality is whether
the restraint imposed is such as merely regulates and perhaps thereby pro-
motes competition or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy
competition. sot
Under "rule of reason" analysis the courts applying section one of the
Sherman Act examine concerted conduct to see if its purpose and effect is to
promote or restrain competition, that is, to increase or decrease allocative effi-
ciency.
502
Thus, agreements that on their face restrain trade may be permis-
sible because they expand a market, improve market functioning or achieve in-
tegrated efficiencies, thus ultimately making the market more efficient.'" For
498 Cf.
W. Lazarus,
supra
note 54, at IV-11, IV-12. This argument has been raised on
appeal in
Wilk.
See Preliminary Brief,
supra
note 494, at 78-81.
499
15 U.S.C. 5 1 (1976).
5
°° Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 59, 60 (1911).
5
°' Board of Trade v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918).
5
°
2
Professional Eng'rs,
435 U.S. at 688-92 (1979); Continental T.V., Inc, v. GTE
Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49, 50 n.16 (1977); Smith v. Pro Football, Inc., 593 F.2d 1173, 1183
(D.C. Cir. 1979).
See
R. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX, 107.60 (1978); Gerhart,
The
Supreme Court and Antitrust Analysis: The Near Triumph of the Chicago School,
1982 SUP. CT.
REV.
319
at 321, 330-32 (1982).
5
°
3
See
M. POLLARD &
R.
LIEBENLUFT,
supra
note 448, at 31-39, Gerhart,
supra
note
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
905
example, commodities exchanges have been permitted to limit trading to day-
time hours to focus the market and make it more competitive.
5
"
This mode of analysis, however, creates high administrative costs for the
courts that must apply it and high costs in accomodating uncertainty for indus-
tries that must anticipate its application.'" To avoid or limit these costs the Su-
preme Court has identified certain practices, that it considers to be manifestly
and per se anticompetitive. These practices include price fixing,
505
market di-
visions,
507
tying arrangements,'" and concerted refusals to deal — boycotts."
9
Once such activities are detected in a particular case, liability follows and fur-
ther analysis is unnecessary. Moreover, in a per se case, the plaintiff need not
establish evidence of actual public injury,
510
and the defendant may not rely on
the reasonableness, or even the procompetitiveness of its conduct for justifica-
tion.'"
Unfortunately, however, the Supreme Court's attempts at simplified per
se analysis have not been wholly successful. In many instances per se rules as
applied by the Supreme Court merely transfer the problem from one of analys-
is to one of characterization.'" This is particularly true for elusive categories
like group boycotts which can often be identified only after analysis that rivals
in complexity the analysis required to apply the rule of reason.
c.
Rule of Reason Analysis
Lower court cases generally have held that rule of reason rather than per
se analysis is the appropriate form of antitrust analysis for certification or
standardization
activities.
513
Moreover, dicta in
recent
Supreme Court opin-
502, at 334-44, Liebenluft & Pollard,
supra
note 448, at 947-50.
"
4
Board of Trade of Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918).
3
"
3
See
Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc'y, 102 S. Ct. 2466, 2472, 2473 (1982).
"6
See id.;
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940); Dr. Miles
Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911).
51
)
7
Market division entails competitors dividing up a market with each taking an ex-
clusive share, thus creating local monopolies. Timken Roller Bearing Co. v. United States, 341
U.S. 593 (1951).
"8
Tying arrangements are discussed
infra
at text accompanying note 539. Northern
Pac. Ry. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1 (1958).
"' Klors, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, 359 U.S. 207 (1959);
Fashion Originators'
Guild of Am., Inc. v. FTC, 312 U.S. 4-57 (1941).
51
° Klors,
359 U.S.
at
213.
Maricopa Co. ,
102 S. Ct. at 2473.
3
'
2
See
Gerhart,
supra
note 502, at 323-25; Ponsoldt,
The Application of Sherman Act Anti-
boycott Law to Industry Self-Regulation: An Analysis Integrating Nonbotcott Sherman Act Principles,
55 S.
CAL. L. REV. 1, 17, 18 (1981).
"3
Gunter Harz Sports v. United States Tennis Ass'n,
1981-82
Trade Cases (CCH)
64,243 (D. Neb. March 4, 1981),
aff'd
1981-82 Trade Cas. 64,381 (8th Cir. Dec. 2, 1981);
Note,
Trade Association Exclusionary Practices: An Affirmative Role for the Rule of Reason,
66 CoLum. L.
REV. 1486, 1487 (1966); Kissam,
First Amendment, supra
note 441 at 164;
see
Structural Laminates
Inc. v. Douglas Fir Plywood Ass'n, 399 F. Supp. 155, 155 (9th Cir. 1968).
906
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
ions indicates that per se rules may not be appropriate for analyzing profes-
sional self-regulation of the quality of professional services.
5
" Thus, the JCAH
standardization and accreditation programs, considered alone, should be anal-
yzed under the rule of reason.
Under the rule of reason, anticompetitive effects of JCAH standards —
for example standards limiting hospital staff privileges of non-physician practi-
tioners — must be justified by the demonstrable procompetitive effects of those
policies.
515
Only procompetitive justifications may be considered: JCAH
policies could not be justified by health and safety benefits that do not in
themselves promote competition.
516
A court reviewing JCAH standards would
need to balance the likelihood and magnitude of injury to competition by those
standards, against the likelihood and magnitude of procompetitive effects of the
JCAH standards at issue. The court would need to consider the effects of
JCAH policies in the specific professional context in which they operate, recog-
nizing that different and perhaps more substantial procompetitive effects may
result from standardization or certification in professional settings than would
be true in commerce or industry.
517
Certification and standardization programs have been justified as procom-
petitive for reasons discussed earlier — they lower search and transaction costs,
permit economies of scale, and facilitate market entry.
5 8
These justifications
only apply, however, to the extent that certification standards are actually
related to quality and a certification program is fairly and objectively con-
ducted.
5
t
9
31'
v. Maricopa County, 102 S. Ct. 2466, 2475 (1982); National Soc'y of Pro-
fessional Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 696 (1978); Goldfarb v. The Virginia State Bar,
421 U.S. 773, 787 n.17 (1975).
See also
Rigler,
Professional Codes of Conduct After Goldfarb: A Proposed
Method of Analysis,
29 ARK. L. REV. 185, 189-91 (1975) (distinguishing between professional
restraints that are commercial in nature, which should be subject to antitrust scrutiny, and those
that are not, which should not be).
5
" See
National Soc'y Professional Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 687-91
(1978); Eliason Corp. v. National Sanitation Found., 614 F.2d 126, 130 (6th Cir. 1980); Hatley
v. American Quarterhorse Ass'n, 552 F.2d 646, 652 (5th Cir. 1977); Bridge Corp. of Am. v.
American Contract Bridge League, Inc., 428 F.2d 1365, 1370 (9th Cir. 1970); Deesen v. Profes-
sional Golfers Ass'n of Am., 358 F.2d 165, 170 (9th Cir. 1966).
316
See National Soc'y Professional Eng'rs,
435 U.S. at 690, 695, 696;
cf.
Health Care
Equalization Comm. of the Iowa Chiropractic Soc'y v. Iowa Med. Soc'y (S.D. Iowa, Ruling
&
order Feb. 12, 1982), striking defendant's public welfare defense in Sherman Act claim. The ad-
mission of evidence concerning non-economic justifications of exclusionary actions aimed at
chiropractors is also on appeal in Wilk v. American Medical Ass'n,
see infra
note 522.
517 National Socy Professional Eng'rs,
435 U.S. at 696;
Goldfarb,
421 U.S. at 787 n.17.
318
See supra
text accompanying notes 248-56.
"9
See Eliason,
614 F.2d at 130;
Bridge Corp.,
428 F.2d at 1370;
Deesen,
358 F.2d
at
170;
POLLARD
&
LIEBENLUFT,
supra
note 448, at 34-37; Liebenluft & Pollard,
supra
note 448, at
947-49.
It is arguable that even a standardization or certification program using unreasonable
standards and unfair certification procedures, such as rules that forbid marketing of non-stand-
ard products, does not violate the Sherman Act. Absent ancillary enforcement mechanisms,
standardization and certification programs directed at consumers only operate to exclude prod-
ucts to the extent that independent consumers rely on the standards or certificates for making
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
907
To assure a real relationship between certification and quality, antitrust
cases applying rule of reason analysis have required that certification programs
use clear, objective and reasonable standards directly related to quality charac-
teristics, and that the entity administering the program have fair procedures to
assure that standards are evenly applied,"° Under rule of reason analysis the
specific anticompetitive and procompetitive effects of JCAH policies would be
addressed on a case by case basis.
Insofar as JCAH standards apply to non-physician practitioners they have
been criticized as being irrational — as totally ignoring the contributions of
non-physician practitioners to health care — and as denying procedural
fairness — excluding non-physician practitioners as a class from hospital prac-
tice and providing no procedure to consider staff privileges for such practition-
ers on an individual basis."' JCAH has defended the standards, claiming they
contribute to hospital quality and are thus procompetitive. In the one case on
this question that has gone to trial, a jury applying rule of reason analysis has
concluded that JCAH standards excluding one group of non-physicians —
chiropractors — from hospitals are not violative of the Sherman Act.
522
d.
Per Se Analysis
To this point we have considered standardization and accreditation pro-
grams as they function independently. JCAH, however, does not exist in a
vacuum, but is the trigger mechanism for a reticulate structure of private and
public programs for rewarding institutions that comply and sanctioning in-
_
their own purchasing decisions. If the standard or certification decisions are unreasonable, this
will in all likelihood eventually dawn on the consumers, who will find other means of choosing
products. Thus in the long run, such programs will not restrain trade. However, where a com-
plex product is involved, not readily subject to evaluation by independent consumer search or ex-
perience, an unreasonable or unfair standardization or certification program may substantially
damage competition over a prolonged period of time. Moreover, if a standardization or certifica-
tion program is not directed at ultimate consumers, but rather at controlling the production of in-
itial or complementary products for the benefit of intermediate or complementary producers, it
may control the production of initial procedures to the detriment of the competitors of those per-
sons directing the standardization or certification program or of consumers.
See
discussion
supra
at
text accompanying notes 323-47. Thus antitrust controls should apply.
52°
Hydrolevel Corp. v. American Soc'y Mech. Eng'rs, 635 F.2d 118, 126 (2d Cir.
1980),
aff'd,
102 S. Ct. 1935 (1982);
see
Silver v. United States Stock Exchange, 373 U.S. 341,
357-67 (1963); Blalock v, Ladies Professional Golf Ass'n, 359 F. Supp. 1210, 1267 (N.D, Ga.
1973); W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at III 90-III 93; Howe & Badger,
supra
note 253, at 381-84;
Ponsoldt,
supra note
512, at 47-50.
521
See generally
cases cited
supra
note 217; Lavine,
supra
note 315, at 20, 21;
but see
Kissam, et al.,
supra note 276, at 680.
522
Wilk v. American Medical Ass'n, No. 76-C-3777 (N.D. III. Jan. 30, 1981),
app.
pending,
No. 81-1331 (7th Cir.). This case is on appeal, however, with the plaintiffs contesting,
in-
ter alia,
the court's permitting the jury to consider non-economic justifications of the JCAH policy
— specifically the legitimacy of chiropractic health care. Preliminary Brief, supra
note 494, at
59-70.
See
Comment,
Professional Association Permitted to Raise Public Welfare just!fication in Defense of
Group Boycott,
60 WASH. U.L.Q. 249 (1982).
908
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24;835
stitutions that fail to comply with the JCAH standards."' Moreover, JCAH
standards require a form of hospital medical staff organization that is itself ex-
clusionary. Taking into account these coercive
elements, per
se analysis might
be appropriate both for analyzing the effects of JCAH on the competitors of its
physician constituency and the competitors of its hospital constituency.
i. Practices Suppressing Competition Against Physicians
An issue in most antitrust litigation brought against JCAH has been the
effects of the JCAH accreditation program on competition between physicians
and non-physician health care practitioners, specifically chiropractors, podi-
atrists, nurse anesthetists and psychologists.
524
There are two possible theories
under which such practitioners, excluded .from or limited in hospital practice
by JCAH hospital standards, could allege a per se illegal boycott by JCAH.
First, they could try to prove that physicians, perhaps acting through re-
presentative organizations like the AMA, have conspired together with hospi-
tals, through the link of the JCAH and perhaps other entities (like the AMA
Liaison Committee on Medical Education or Blue Cross Associations) to boy-
cott non-physician practitioners and their patients. The hospitals boycott the
non-physician practitioners by refusing to permit them admitting privileges
and boycott the patients of non-physician practitioners by refusing to allow
them admission, except under the supervision of doctors.
525
Characterized in this way, the accreditation program resembles the facts
in cases where retailers have conspired with wholesalers to deny other com-
peting retailers needed goods,
526
or where suppliers of goods and services have
conspired together to deny their competitors
access
to necessary facilities under
their control."' Insofar as the boycott is directed at patients, this characteriza-
tion of the JCAH accreditation program also resembles the facts in per se
cases
in which suppliers have boycotted buyers to
coerce
the buyers to cease dealing
with competitors of the suppliers."' Under this characterization, the JCAH ac-
creditation program can be classified as a boycott or a refusal to deal, a per se
violation of the antitrust laws."'
523
See supra
notes 58-74 and accompanying text.
524
See
cases cited
supra
note 217.
"' Cf.
Blue Shield of Va. v. McCready, 102 S. Ct. 3540 (1982) as to consumers' stan-
ding to sue for injuries resulting from such a boycott.
526
United States v. General Motors, 384 U.S. 127 (1966); Klor's Inc. v. Broadway-
Hale Stores, 359 U.S. 207 (1959); Dolan & Ralston,
supra
note 304, at 752-59.
527
See
Associated Press v, United States, 326 U.S. 1 (1945); United States v. Terminal
R. Ass'n of St. Louis, 224 U.S. 383 (1912); U.S. Dental Inst. v. American Ass'n of Orthodon-
tists, 396
F.
Supp. 565, 580-81 (N.D. Ill. 1975);
but see
Kissam et al.,
supra
note 276, at 657, 659.
728
See
Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1981);
Fashion Originators Guild of Am. v. FTC, 312 U.S. 457 (1941).
Cf.
Feminist Women's Health
Union v. Mohammad, 586 F.2d 530 (5th Cir. 1978),
cert. denied,
444 U.S. 924 (1979) (claiming
that doctors were refusing to treat patients of plaintiff's abortion clinic in effort to eliminate com-
petition from plaintiff).
529
This type of arrangement has also been criticized as a "private economic govern-
July 19831
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
909
Second, the JCAH accreditation program could be characterized as a con-
certed effort by physicians, the JCAH, and other professional organizations to
compel hospitals to refuse to deal with non-physician practitioners and their
patients. Here the hospitals would be co-victims of the conspiracy rather than
co-conspirators. Under this characterization the JCAH accreditation program
would somewhat resemble boycotts in which retailers have boycotted whole-
salers to eliminate competition.
53
° This characterization fits less comfortably
under the conventional definition of boycott as a concerted coerced refusal to
deal that directly excludes a competitor from a market."' Under the earlier
characterization the elements and direction of coercion and exclusion were
clear: non-physician practitioners and their patients were explicitly barred
from the market of hospital practice through the denial of staff privileges by co-
operating hospitals. Under the second characterization the element of coercion
is the denial of certification directed in the first instance against the hospital. In
general, whether denial of certification by a certification program is coercive is
a question of fact, and depends upon the actual power of a certification pro-
gram to bring to bear economic pressure to exclude from a market an entity
refused certification.
532
The coercive power of JCAH against hospitals is open
to question. There is no explicit professional requirement forbidding doctors
from cooperating with or practicing in hospitals not accredited by JCAH; in
fact, non-accredited hospitals do exist, are staffed by physicians and even par-
ticipate in Medicare.
533
Moreover, because the coercion in the second
characterization is aimed at hospitals in the first instance rather than at compe-
titors of the boycotting physicians, the courts may have difficulty characteriz-
ing the activity as a per se illegal group boycott.
534
On the other hand, the an-
cillary economic (and regulatory) consequences of a JCAH non-accreditation
decision exert substantial coercive force against non-accredited hospitals."
5
And the ultimate targets of this boycott are the non-physician practitioner corn-
ment." W. Lazarus,
supra
note 72, at 111-83.
'" See
Eastern States Retail Lumber Dealers Ass'n v. United States, 234 U.S. 600
(1914).
"' See
Note,
Restrictive Practices in Accreditation of Medical Schools: An Antitrust Analysis,
51 S.
CAL. L. REV. 657, 684, 685 (1978); Comment,
Boycott: A Specific Definition Limits the Applicability
of the Per Se Rule, 71
Nw. U.L. REV. 818, 823 (1977).
532
See
Paralegal Inst. v. American Bar Assoc., 475 F. Supp. 1123, 1130 (E.D.N.Y.
1979); W. Lazarus, supra note 72, at 111-91, 111-96.
533
percent
of
all the nation's hospitals are non-accredited. Affeldt,
supra
note
45, at 95.
534 Smith v. Pro Football, 593 F.2d 1173, 1179 (D.C. Cir. 1979); cf.
St. Paul Fire and
Marine Ins. Co. v. Barry, 438 U.S. 531, 542 and n.14 (1973) (in dicta leaving open the question
of whether a boycott must be intended to suppress competition to be a per se antitrust violation).
See also
Ponsoldt,
supra
note 500, at 59 (identifying a horizontal [competitive] relationship be-
tween plaintiff and defendants as a necessary element of a per se group boycott) and Marrese v.
American Academy of Orthopedic Surgeons, 692 F.2d 1083, 1093-94 (7th Cir. 1982) (stating
boycotts are not illegal per se unless they further other per se illegal anticompetitive agreements).
535
See supra
text accompanying notes 64-74.
910
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
petitors of the perpetrators of the boycott. Thus even under this characteriza-
tion a court could find a per se illegal boycott.
ii. Practices Suppressing Competition Against Hospitals
JCAH may also be engaged in anticompetitive conduct favoring its other
constitutency, the institutional providers of health care. JCAH accredits not
only hospitals but also institutional health care programs such as long-term
care facilities, psychiatric hospitals, drug and alcohol treatment programs, and
facilities for the mentally retarded."
6
Though JCAH accredits principally
medical institutions, many of the programs carried on in these institutions
could be delivered equally well in a non-medical institution. For example,
some facilities for the mentally ill or developmentally disabled rely heavily on
psychology or social work, and utilize only minimally the medical services of
physicians or psychiatrists. Substance abuse could be addressed by communi-
ty-based social services providers rather than by hospital-based medical pro-
grams. Yet, where JCAH accreditation is required for government licensure or
participation in private insurance programs such as Blue Cross, substance
abuse programs that do not rely on a medical treatment model may be exclud-
ed. This exclusion will limit competition against hospitals and hospital-based
programs. This in turn may raise consumer costs.
557
The JCAH policies sup-
porting this exclusion might be found to violate the antitrust laws under rule of
reason analysis similar to that discussed earlier.
Two per se violation theories could be used to challenge exclusion of non-
medical programs from JCAH accreditation. First, these exclusions could
again be characterized as a concerted refusal to deal, a boycott, this time
directed by hospitals against their competitors. The coercive effects of JCAH
denial of accreditation when combined with the requirements of private insur-
ance programs or state licensing laws for accreditation may constitute sufficient
coercion to ground a per se challenge.
Second, JCAH's all-or-none policy
5
" could in some instances be
characterized as a tying arrangement, a per se violation of the antitrust law.
539
Through its all-or-none policy JCAH may be able to discourage some hospitals
from expanding and diversifying into more efficient and competitive non-
medical health care delivery programs, and thus protect other hospitals from
"8
See supra
notes 40-43.
537
See M.D. Surplus Could Incite Opposition to Nurse Midw1fe Market Intrusion,
12 moo.
HEALTH CARE,
Nov. 1982 at 102, 103 (reporting that a midwife supervised delivery in a birthing
center costs only 405 of a normal inpatient delivery).
"8
See supra
text accompanying note 319.
"9
See
Northern Pac. Ry, v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5-6 (1958); Bogus v. American
Speech and Hearing Ass'n, 582 F.2d 277, 285-88 (3rd Cir. 1978); Dolan & Ralston,
supra
note
304 at 756-63.
A tying arrangement exists where a seller enjoying competitive advantages in the market
for a tying product requires buyers of that product also to buy an economically severable tied
product, thus restraining competition in the market for the tied product. Northern Pac. Ry. v.
United States, 356 U.S. at 5-6 (1958); L. SULLIVAN,
supra
note 490 at § 150. If JCAH carries out
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
911
competition. Certification of hospitals and of other health care delivery pro-
grams are clearly economically severable services. JCAH obviously controls
the market for the tying product, hospital accreditation. Indeed, in some
markets JCAH has been granted a monopoly over this product by law.'"
Therefore, the all-or-none policy which ties the purchase of the tied product —
accreditation of the non-hospital (e.g., substance abuse or developmental dis-
abilities) program — to the purchase of the tying product — hospital accredita-
tion — meets all the requirements of the classic definition of a tying arrange-
ment, a per se antitrust violation."'
3. JCAH Monopolization
The JCAH standardization and accreditation programs may also violate
Section two of the Sherman Act, forbidding monopolization.
542
To establish a
violation of Section two, a plaintiff would have to show that JCAH has unlaw-
fully monopolized the market in health care certification in the United States to
the exclusion of other certification agencies.
The first step in determining whether a monopoly in fact exists is to iden-
tify the arena for the defendant's market power in terms of both the geographic
and product market in which the seller competes.
543
The Supreme Court in
United States v. E. I. Dupont de Nemours & Co.
544
defined a product market as in-
cluding all goods and services that are reasonably interchangeable, i.e. goods
and services that may be substituted for those of the seller if the seller raises his
price. The courts have defined geographic market as the territory from which
competitors of the alleged monopolist's product are excluded by high transac-
tion costs."' To find that a monopoly exists a court need not find that the de-
fendant has taken over an entire product market within an entire geographic
market, but the court must find that the defendant controls a substantial pro-
portion of both markets.
546
JCAH accredits eighty percent of the nation's hospitals and has no com-
petition for the accreditation of non-osteopathic hospitals."' Its share of the
total health institution accreditation market in the United States is smaller, but
within this market JCAH has no substantial competition and arguable mono-
poly power.
its present plan to regulate evaluation of hospital based mental health facilities under the AMH,
the presence of an illegal tying arrangement would be even clearer.
See supra
note 320.
'
4
° Cf.
Blumstein & Calvani,
State Action as a Shield and Sword in a Medical Services
Antitrust
Context,
1978 DUKE L.J. 389, 435-36 (1978) (discussing the reliance on state created monopolies
to establish market power to ground tying arrangements).
341
See supra
note 539.
342
See
15 U.S.C. $ 2 (1976).
54
' Sce
L. SULLIVAN,
supra
note 490, at 55 12, 19.
544
351 U.S. 377, 393-95 (1956).
See
Robinson v. McGovern, 521 F. Supp. 842, 879 (W.D. Pa. 1981); Dolan &
Ralston,
supra
note 304, at 765, 766.
"6
See
Dolan & Ralston,
supra
note 304, at 766 and n.278.
547
See
Affeldt,
supra
note 53, at 189.
912
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
To establish Section two liability, it is not enough for a plaintiff to show
merely the existence of monopoly power. The plaintiff must also show that the
defendant willfully acquired the monopoly power, that it is not merely the
result of a "superior product, business acumen, or historical accident.
P548
JCAH could well argue that its dominance in the health care accreditation field
results from the quality of its work, from government recognition, or perhaps
from the fact that the service of information production through standardi-
zation and certification is a natural monopoly. Even if it could be demonstrated
that JCAH sought and obtained government sanction for its monopoly posi-
tion, such conduct would probably be protected by
Noerr-Pennington
549
and not
be vulnerable to a Section two charge. On the other hand, if it could be shown
that JCAH excluded competition from other accreditation bodies through or-
ganizing or cooperating in concerted refusals to deal — as by obtaining cooper-
ation from Blue Cross to refuse to reimburse facilities accredited by com-
petitors — or through tying arrangements, a violation of Section two could be
established.
55
°
If Section two litigation served no purpose other than to further illuminate
and sanction conduct already illegal under Section one, it would probably not
be worth the effort. Section two, however, might also serve as the basis for gov-
ernment litigation to compel JCAH to divest itself of its non-hospital accredita-
tion programs. This could result in the development of new accreditation pro-
grams which in turn might encourage greater diversity and competition in the
health care industry.
4. Effects of Antitrust Litigation on JCAH
JCAH has not been blind to the ramifications of antitrust law for its pro-
grams, nor has it failed to take note of the litigation against it. It appears that
JCAH in its most recent AMH rewrite, may be retreating from standards ex-
cluding non-physician health care providers from hospitals."' This move
seems to be largely attributable to antitrust litigation against JCAH, and
testifies to the potential of antitrust litigation to control the anticompetitive ef-
5"
United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-571 (1966); Eliason v. National
Sanitation Foundation, 614 F.2d 126, 130, 131 (6th Cir. 1980);
see also
Roof Fire Alarm Co. v.
Royal Indemnity Co., 202 F. Supp. 166, 168, 169 (F.D. Tenn. 1963),
aff'd,
313 F.2d 635 (6th
Cir. 1963),
cert. denied,
373 U.S. 949 (1963) (widespread acceptance of standard setting organiza-
tion because of its competence, not monopolization); Veizaga v. National Bd. for Respiration
Therapy, 1977-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) 61,274 (N.D. Ill., Jan. 27, 1977) (case dismissed against
health practitioner certifying organization as plaintiff failed to allege willful acquisition or main-
taining of monopoly power).
549
See supra
text accompanying notes 432-35.'
"° See
Sullivan,
supra
note 490, at SS 33-48.
551 See
Harrington,
/CAN Board Drops Medical Staff Requirement,
PSYCHIATR IR
Nrwc,
Jan. 7, 1983 at 1, 8, 9; Robinson,
Medical Staff Standards May Be Eased,
MOD,
HEALTH
CARE,
March, 1983 at 23;
AMA Acts on Doctors' Plight at Hospitals,
MED.
WORLD NEWS,
Jan. 10, 1982 at
35;
Revised Hospital Standards Threaten Roosts Long Ruled by Doctors and Denitsts,
MED. WORLD
NEWS,
July 19, 1982 at 33-34.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
913
fects of private standardization and certification efforts. JCAH earlier settled a
case brought against it by podiatrists by substantially expanding the recogni-
tion of the role of podiatrists in hospitals under JCAH standards.'" It may well
be that if JCAH is closely monitored by interested parties and by the Justice
Department, the anticompetitive effects of its programs may be reduced to an
acceptable level and the procompetitive effects strengthened.'"
B.
Control of Inadequate Standards and Inspections Through Tort Law
An evaluation of JCAH must also take into account the fact that the
JCAH inspection and accreditation program is not the only, and indeed may
not be the most effective, means of assuring hospital compliance with JCAH
standards.
Following the Illinois Supreme Court's lead in
Darling v. Charleston Com-
munity Hospital,
551
courts
increasingly have relied on JCAH standards for eval-
uating whether or not hospital practices are negligent,
555
or for rejecting the
"locality rule," under which negligence is evaluated in terms of practice in the
community in which medical care is given, in favor of national standards like
those of JCAH.
556
Though hospitals may be able to deceive JCAH inspectors
as to compliance with JCAH standards, hospitals that attempt to do so may
eventually face substantial negligence judgments. Prudent hospitals will pur-
sue risk management programs structured around compliance with JCAH
standards to limit tort exposure.
3
"
Reliance on JCAH standards to define reasonable hospital behavior
could, of course, lower the quality of care rather than raise it. Some critics have
claimed that JCAH has purposely weakened its standards to protect hospitals
552
Levin v. JCAH, 354 F.2d.515 (D.C. Cir. 1965);
see
Shaw v. Hospital Authority of
Cobb County, 614 F.2d 646 (5th Cir. 1980); Hollowell,
The Growing Legal Contest — Hospital
Privileges for Podiatrists,
23 ST. LOUIS U.L.J. 491, 501 n.55 (1979).
"3
An additional source of potential control over JCAH anticompetitive activities is the
Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. 55 41-58 (1976). After an extensive preliminary in-
vestigation,
see
Schlicke,
supra
note 180, at 27, the FTC decided that it did not have jurisdiction
over JCAH. Telephone interview with Joan Moreland, FTC (July 27, 1982);
see
15 U.S.C.
(1976).
"' 33 Ill. 2d 326, 211 N.E.2d 253 (1965),
cert. denied,
383 U.S. 946 (1966).
"' Steves v. United States, 294 F. Supp. 446, 454, 455 (D.S.C. 1968); Fox v. Cohen,
84 III. App. 3d 744, 750, 406 N.E.2d 178, 182 (1980); Silkret v. Annapolis Emergency Hosp.
Ass'n, 276 Md. 187, 349 A.2d 245, 254 (1975);
cf.
Hunsaker v. Bozeman Deaconess Found.,
588 P.2d 493, 502 (Mont. 1976) (JCAH standards accepted into evidence by trial court as part of
plaintiff's cases).
"6
Kapuschinsky v. United States, 248 F. Supp. 732, 744 (D.S.C. 1966); Rucker v.
High Point Mem. Hosp., 285 N.C. 519, 524, 206 S.E.2d 196, 201, 202 (1974); Durling v.
Bluefield Sanatorium, Inc., 149 W. Va. 567, 142 S.E.2d 754, 765 (1965); Lundlam,
The Impact
of the Darling Decision Upon the Practice of Medicine & Hospitals,
11 THE FORUM 756, 757, 758
(1976).
"
7
See
R.
Dalton,
Reducing Risks Through Compliance with Accreditation Standards,
6
QUALI-
TY REV. BULL. 3.4 (1980); Passett,
The "Systems Approach" to Patient Safety: An Update,
9 LEGAL
ASPECTS MED. PRAC. Apr. 1981 1, 1-3.
914
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
from tort liability.
558
Moreover, some hospitals are now relying on compliance
with JCAH standards to defend the reasonableness of their practices against
claims that the hospital's care was inadequate.
555
Nevertheless, the role of
JCAH standards in tort litigation probably encourages better quality care and
treatment.
Tort actions are also a potential means of getting directly at the problem of
inadequate JCAH standards and inspections. In a number of recent hospital
negligence cases, plaintiffs have added the JCAH as an additional defendant,
claiming that JCAH is a guarantor of the quality of care in and responsible for
the negligence of accredited hospitals.'" The barriers facing a plaintiff in such
a lawsuit are readily apparent. As the major function of JCAH is to serve as a
consultant to the hospital, it may be hard to show a duty owed by JCAH to in-
dividual patients. It may also be difficult to establish that JCAH proximately
caused any particular negligence by a hospital or physician. The general ignor-
ance of JCAH accreditation would make it difficult for any plaintiff to claim
that JCAH could foresee actual reliance on its accreditation as a guarantor of
quality. Finally, establishing that JCAH standards or inspections were
negligent will not be easy.
The use of tort litigation against JCAH is also questionable from a policy
standpoint. If the purpose of tort litigation is to spread risks,
56
' JCAH is a poor
candidate. JCAH is not only not a "deep pocket," but it is also a poor insurer.
If the purpose is to encourage expenditure of resources to prevent an injury
commensurate with the likely extent of the injury ,
552
JCAH is again an inap-
propriate defendant. Medical injuries normally are caused by the failure of a
hospital or physician to take adequate precautions by the expenditure of ade-
quate resources rather than by a failure of JCAH. But, in other contexts some
courts have held independent certifying or testing agencies liable under a
negligent misrepresentation theory to ultimate consumers for injuries caused
by approved products,
5
" and such litigation may be on the increase against
JCAH.
Ultimately, such cases may do more harm than good to the quality of care
hospital patients as a group receive. If JCAH became a routine defendant in
53°
See Hearings, supra
note 54, at 1954, 1972 (testimony of Fred Hiestand).
559
See
Elam v. College Park Hosp., 132 Cal. App. 3d 332 (1982); Moreaux v. Argonaut
Ins. Co., 350 So.2d 240, 246 (La. Ct. App. 1977),
cert. denied,
351 So.2d 776 (La. 1977).
See also
Pelphrey v. United States, 674 F.2d 243 (4th Cir. 1982) (JCAH accreditation of hospital cited as
fact supporting granting of summary judgment to defendant in malpractice action).
36°
See
cases cited
supra
note 219.
"' See
C. Morris & C. R. Morris, Jr., Morris on
Torts,
232-37 (2d Ed. 1980).
562
Posner,
Economic Analysis of Law,
122-25 (1977).
563
See
Hempstead v. General Fire Extinguisher Corp., 269 F. Supp. 109 (D. Del. 1967)
(Underwriters Laboratories may be liable, if negligent, for injuries caused by explosion of ap-
proved fire extinguishers); Hanberry v. Hearst Corp., 276 Cal. App. 2d 820, 81 Cal. Rptr. 519
(1969) (plaintiff states cause of action under negligent misrepresentation theory against Hearst
Corp. for injury caused by shoes covered by Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval).
July 19831
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
915
hospital negligence actions, its exposure for legal fees alone, even if it con-
sistently won the lawsuits, would for a time be staggering.'" The result might
well be to eliminate JCAH, and its beneficial effects.
C.
Federal Supplementation
The 1972 amendments to the Social Security Act provide another means
for improving the quality of care in JCAH accredited facilities. These amend-
ments, described earlier,
565
permit the Secretary of HEW (now HHS) to prom-
ulgate standards in excess of those required by JCAH standards; to validate
JCAH accreditation with inspections by state agencies on a random and
substantial complaint basis; and to decertify accredited facilities if they are
found not to be in substantial compliance with HEW certification standards.
Implementation of these amendments has been largely inadequate: the state
validation program has been characterized by a GAO report as inconsistent
and ineffective.
566
Furthermore, recent validation regulations issued by the
Department of Health and Human Services"' require state survey agency
monitoring of accredited facilities with substantial deficiencies only if JCAH
refuses itself to monitor deficiencies or HHS otherwise determines state review
necessary. As of the 1978 GAO report, HHS had never decertified an ac-
credited hospital."' Finally, HHS has never in fact promulgated any standards
higher than JCAH standards, and has committed itself not to promulgate
higher standards without first consulting JCAH.
569
Nevertheless, the 1972 amendments permit HHS to take a more active
role in the standardization and certification process. While the arguments
made earlier
570
demonstrate that it is unwise for HHS to duplicate JCAH
regulatory efforts, an HHS role is particularly appropriate for filling the gaps
left by JCAH regulation of hospital quality and for encouraging competition.
In particular, HHS should focus its standard setting authority on quality of
36+
Of course, if JCAH consistently won, plaintiffs would cease suing it. If the idea of su-
ing JCAH became popular, however, it might take some time for the law to become dear, and
JCAH could encounter substantial expenses in the interim.
563
See supra
text accompanying notes 185-87.
566
GAO REPORT,
supra
note 207, at 16-21.
367
45 Fed. Reg. 74, 826 (1980) (codified at 42 C.F.R. §§ 405.1901, 405.1902 (1981)).
368
GAO REPORT,
supra
note 207, at 14.
569
Telephone interview with Spencer Colburn, Hospital Services Branch, Health
Standards and Quality Bureau, Health Care Finance and Administration, Department of
Health and Human Services (Sept. 17, 1982). In 1978, HEW issued regulations concerning
quality control and proficiency testing standards for laboratories in Medicare hospitals that
would have exceeded JCAH standards, but delayed full implementation for nine months.
See 43
Fed. Reg. 7984 (1978). By the time the rule was to be fully operational JCAH standards were
upgraded to equivalency; thus, independent surveys were never begun.
See
44 Fed. Reg. 3288
(1979). A general revision of hospital certification standards proposed by HHS on January 4,
1983 does not propose standards exceeding those of JCAH. In fact, it is an attempt to comply
with a proposed JCAH revision of its standards. 48 Fed. Reg. 299, 300 (1983).
"° See supra
text accompanying notes 369-75.
916
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
hospital care output and on health care inputs not directly of interest to physi-
cians. It should also encourage the availability of alternatives for patient care
where appropriate. Finally, HHS should use the validation process to assure
enforcement where JCAH has been clearly remiss in its efforts.
D.
Government Review of JCAH Accreditation
Finally, JCAH ought to be subject to government review in its exercise of
delegated authority. This is not only good policy, but is required by the con-
stitutionally based nondelegation doctrine which restricts the delegation of au-
thority from the government to private entities. Early nondelegation cases pri-
marily addressed the issue of delegation of policy-making authority from the
legislative to executive or judicial branches."' This application of the
nondelegation doctrine rests on the principle that in a representative
democracy the responsibility to make policy ultimately resides with the legisla-
ture — there is an irreducible minimum of responsibility that it cannot dele-
gate.'" The appropriate function of the executive branch as articulated in early
nondelegation cases is to make subordinate rules, attend to details, and deter-
mine facts.
573
Subordination of the executive to the legislature is not only
necessary to preserve representative government, but also to provide criteria
for judicial review of executive decisions and actions."
4
Despite doctrinal limits on delegation of power from Congress to the exec-
utive branch, actual attempts to limit such delegation have largely failed. The
complex and highly technical nature of problems faced by government, as well
as its need to act rapidly and flexibly in changing situations, requires concen-
tration of considerable policy-making authority in the executive branch.
575
Moreover, the legislative branch is subject to political pressures from which ad-
ministrators are more insulated by anonymity and the civil service laws. These
pressures render it more difficult for the legislature to make controversial pro-
grammatic decisions and encourage abandonment of such decisions to the ex-
ecutive.
576
5
" See, e.g.,
Hampton & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394 (1928); Buttfield v.
Stranahan, 192 U.S. 470 (1904); Field v. Clark, 143 U.S. 649 (1892); Wayman v. Southard, 23
U.S. 1 (1825).
572
S.
BARBER, THE CONSTITUTION AND THE DELEGATION OF CONGRESSIONAL
POWER 18 (1975); Note,
Rethinking the Nondelegation Doctrine,
62 B.U.L. REV. 257, 260-64, 314-23
(1982).
5"
See, e.g.,
Buttfield v. Stranahan, 192 U.S. 470 (1904) (Congress can delegate power
to administer law to bring about result Congress sets out); Field v. Clark, 143 U.S. 649, 691-94
(1892) (Congress can delegate authority to determine
facts); cf.
Wayman v. Southard, 23 U.S. 1
at 42, 43 (1825) (Congress can delegate to courts power to 611 up the details of legislation to
regulate practice).
576
See Note,
B.U.L.
REV.,
supra
note 572, at 295, 296.
"
5
See
Amalgamated Meat Cutters & Butcher Workers v. Connelly, 337 F. Supp. 737,
746, 747
(D.D.C.
1971).
But see
Aranson, Gellhorn & Robinson,
A Them)) of Legislative Delegation,
68 CORNELL
L.
REV. 1, 21-24 (1982) (arguing that managerial explanations are not fully ade-
quate to explain the phenomenon of delegation).
"6
See
Barber,
supra
note 572, at 3-4.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
917
Delegation is particularly likely if sharp conflict between groups with vary-
ing interests makes it politically attractive for the legislature to maintain an am-
biguous position on an issue and delegate responsibility to act to the
executive."' The legislative branch is also likely to delegate authority to the ex-
ecutive if it can thereby confer benefits on politically focused groups, thus gain-
ing their approbation, while at the same time shifting responsibility — and the
risk of public disapproval — to the executive.
5
'
8
Though the principle of limit-
ing delegation from the legislature to the executive continues to show signs of
lingering vitality,
579
courts have long recognized the practical need for allowing
delegation of extensive discretionary power to the executive
580
and having
bow to pressure from the legislature permitted a. steady weakening of this
branch of the non delegation doctrine."'
Delegation of legislative authority to a private entity rather than to a coor-
dinate branch of government threatens more directly the ideal of represen-
tative democracy that grounds the non delegation doctrine. Even though the
executive may be less directly answerable to the people than the legislature, it is
still accountable through election of major officials, legislative approval of
significant appointed officials, and laws requiring fair and open executive rule-
making and adjudicatory procedures. Substantial dangers arise when legisla-
tive or executive power is transferred to private bodies neither accountable nor
responsible to the people.
582
These problems are most acute when the private
policymaker is responsible to private groups whose interests potentially are in
conflict with those of the public. It is particularly offensive for the government
to transfer authority to a private body to not only make policy but also quasi-
judicial decisions affecting the rights of specific persons. Such private applica-
tion of policy raises serious fairness and due process problems.
583
Again, this is
5"
Aranson, Gellhorn & Robinson,
supra
note 575, at 59-62.
5"
Id.
at 556-59.
"9
See
Industrial Union Dept. v. American Petroleum Inst., 448 U.S. 607, 672-76
(1980) (Rehnquist, J., concurring).
58
° United States v. Grimaud, 220 U.S. 506, 516 (1911); Buttfield v. Stranahan, 192
U.S. 470, 496 (1904). ,
See
FPC v. New England Power Co., 415 U.S. 345, 352, 353 n.1 (1976) (Marshall,
J. concurring); Quincy College v. Burlington N. R.R., 328 F. Supp, 808, 811 (N.D. I11. 1971),
aff'd.,
405 U.S. 906 (1972).
5"
See
Carter v. Carter Coal Co., 298 U.S. 238 (1936);
see generally,
discussing delega-
tion to private groups: Jaffe,
Law Making By Private Groups,
51
HARV.
L.
REV.
201
(1937); Lieb-
man,
Delegation to Private Parties in American Constitutional Law,
50
IND.
L.J.
650 (1975); Wirtz,
Government by Private Groups,
13 LA. L.
REV.
440 (1953); Note,
The State Courts and Delegation of
Public Authority to Private Groups,
67
HARV.
L.
REV.
1398 (1954) (hereinafter cited as Note,
The
State Courts and Delegation).
3B3
See, e.g. ,
Carter v. Carter Coal Co., 298 U.S. 238, 311-12 (1936); Group Health Ins.
of N.J. v. Howell, 40 N.J. 436, 193 A.2d 103
(1963);
Fink v. Cole, 302 N.Y. 216, 97 N.E.2d 873
(1951); Farias v. City of New York, 101 Misc. 2d 598, 421 N.Y.S.2d 753 (1979); United Chiro-
practors of Washington, Inc. v. Washington, 90 Wash. 2d 1, 578 P.2d 38
(1978);
Liebman,
supra
note 582, at 659-61; Note, The State Courts and Delegation,
supra note 582, at 1401-04.
918
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
particularly true if the interests of the private decision-maker conflict with the
interests of those subject to it or of the public.
584
Government may, however, delegate its power to private parties under
certain conditions. In fact, such delegation is common: through private civil
law the government extensively delegates its authority by affording private par-
ties its power to enforce private agreements, remedy private injuries, or recon-
cile conflicting private property claims, often on the basis of the public interest.
It even creates enforceable private rights as a means of effectuating public pol-
icy."' Moreover, whether or not they are explicitly granted power to make
public policy, private entities exert significant influence over governmental de-
cisions at both the policy determination and implementation leve1.
586
Where
private groups possess specific expertise or unique administrative resources, or
where public problems affect primarily a small cohesive group, it may be rea-
sonable for the government to delegate some power to private bodies to make,
or even enforce, policy."'
Delegation of public authority to a private entity is a particularly rational
legislative strategy if the legislature confronts simultaneously a focused private
interest group — the constituency of the private entity — and an apathetic or
ignorant public, that may be harmed by the delegation but is unlikely im-
mediately to respond. By delegating authority to the private entity, the
legislature can gain the private group's support while risking little public
blame.
588
If the public subsequently becomes aware of the private entity acting
contrary to its interests, there is nothing to stop the legislature turning on
"
4
See, e.g.,
State Bd. of Dry Cleaners v. Thrift-D-Lux Cleaners, 40 Cal. 2d 436, 254
P.2d 29 (1953); People v. Pollution Control Bd., 83 Ill. App. 3d 802, 404 N. E.2d 352 (1980);
Johnson v. Michigan Milk Marketing Board, 295 Mich. 644, 295 N.W. 346 (1940); Group
Health Ins. of N.J. v. Howell, 40 N.J. 439, 193 A.2d 103 (1963); United Trust Co. v. Simmons,
116 Utah 422, 211 P.2d 190 (1949).
585
Hanslowe,
Regulation by Visible Public and Invisible Private Government,
40 TEX . L. REV.
88, 92-113 (1961); Jaffe,
supra
note 582, at 212-21; Note,
The State Courts and Delegation, supra
note
582, at 1399.
'
6
° Wirtz,
supra
note 582, at 457-60.
"' See, e.g. ,
Packer v. Bd. of Behavioral Science Examiners, 52 Cal. App. 3d 190, 125
Cal. Rptr. 96 (1975) (licensing requirement of degree from accredited college upheld); Natural
Milk Producers Ass'n v. City and County of San Francisco, 20 Cal. 2d 101, 124 P.2d 25 (1942)
(municipal reliance on milk standard established by medical experts approved); Colorado
Polytechnic College v. State Bd. of Community Colleges and Occupational Educ., 173 Colo. 39,
476 P.2d 38 (1970) (professional training and experience of educational accounting body justifies
legislative reliance); Florida Welding and Erection Service v. American Mut. Ins. Co. of Boston,
285 So. 2d 386 (Fla. 1973) (permissible to rely on private insurance rating service where
guidelines and standards' established by legislation); Cities Serv. v. Koeneke, 137 Kan. 7, 20
P.2d 460 (1933) (statute exempting from regulation securities listed with New York, Boston and
Chicago stock exchanges approved because of standing and responsibility of those bodies);
Humane Soc'y of United States N.J. Branch v. New Jersey State Fish & Game Council, 70 N.J.
565, 362 A.2d 20 (1976) (no conflict of interest); Morgan v. N.Y. Racing Ass'n, 72 A.D.2d 740,
421 N.Y.S.2d 249
.
(1979) (state reliance on preexisting register of thoroughbred pedigrees ap-
proved).
'a°
See
Aranson, Gellhorn & Robinson,
supra
note 575, at 56-59.
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
919
and criticizing the entity, thereby gaining public approval."
9
Delegation to
private entities, like delegation to the executive, has frequently been upheld by
the courts. Indeed, federal courts have increasingly accepted delegation to
private parties subject to certain safeguards and rarely hold such delegations
improper.
59
° Courts are particularly likely to find delegation unobjectionable
where the circumstances of the delegation provide some assurances of account-
ability and fairness.
First, courts consider it more appropriate for the legislature to adopt ex-
isting articulations of private policy than to delegate prospectively to a private
body continuing power to make policy for the government. A number of cases
have approved government adoption of preexisting private product or profes-
sional service certification standards."' Here accountability is assured by in-
dependent government review of the standards before adoption. Adoption of a
body of private standards, however, including all future changes to those
standards has been held improper, since this effectively delegates unreviewable
discretion to private entities to modify government policy thereafter at their
own initiative.
592
Second, a number of courts have upheld legislation permitting private en-
tities the option of participating in a government regulation program once that
program has been established. For example, the Supreme Court has on several
occasions upheld legislation permitting industries to accept or reject legislative
industry codes, holding that the legislature's actions were proper both in mak-
ing the policy articulated in the code and in providing for optional implementa-
tion
.
593
Third, courts have been more hospitable towards delegation of power
where articulated legislative standards canalize the scope of the private discre-
tion.
594
Here the standards assure that the legislature has made basic policy
589
Id.
at 58.
"° See
Corum v. Beth Israel Medical Center, 373 F. Supp, 550, 553 (S. D. N.Y. 1974);
Quincy College and Seminary Corp. v. Burlington N. R. R., 328 F. Supp. 808, 811 (N.D. Ill.
1971),,aff'd, 405 U.S. 906 (1972).
59'
See, e:g.,
Noblecraft Indus. Inc. v. Secretary of Labor, 614 F.2d 199, 203 (9th Cir.
1980); Attwood v. State
ex
rd
Newman, 53 So. 2d 825 (Fla. 1951); Spencer v. Hunt, 109 Fla.
248, 147 So. 282 (1933); City of Warren v. State Construction Code Comm'n., 66 Mich. App.
493, 239 N.W.2d 640 (1976); Allen v. State Bd. of Veterinarians, 72 R.I. 372, 52 A.2d 131
(1947).
592
See, e.g.,
City of Tucson v. Stewart, 45 Ariz. 36, 40 P.2d 72 (1935); State v.
Crawford, 104 Kan. 141, 177 P. 360 (1919); State
ex rel
Kirschner v. Urquhart, 50 Wash. 2d 131,
310 P.2d 261 (1957).
593
United States v. Rock Royal Coop., 307 U.S. 533, 577-78 (1939); Currin v.
Wallace, 306 U.S. 1, 15 (1939).
See also
Brock v. Superior Court, 9 Cal. 2d 291, 71 P.2d 209
(1937); Palmer Oil Corp. v. Phillips Petroleum, 204 Okla. 543, 231 P.2d 997 (Okla. 1951) (state
court cases similarly upholding industry codes).
594
See, e.g.,
Mount Vernon Mem. Park v. Board of Funeral Directors and Embalmers,
79 Cal. App. 3d 874, 145 Cai. Rptr. 275 (1978); Florida Welding and Erection Service, Inc. v.
American Mut. Ins. Co. of Boston, 285 So. 2d 386 (Fla. 1973); Superintending School Comm'n
v. Bangor Educ. Ass'n, 433 A.2d 383 (Me. 1981); In re Garrison, 44 N.C. App. 158, 260 S.E.2d
920
BOSTON COLLEGE LAW REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
decisions. Similarly, courts have been more willing to permit delegation where
there are external safeguards to assure the proper exercise of authority.
595
This
may be true where standards have a scientific basis or were developed for pur-
poses independent of the governmental program at issue by experts unlikely to
be affected by improper influences such as conflicts of interests.
596
Finally, courts are more willing to approve delegation of authority to
private entities, even authority to make quasi-judicial determinations, where
the private entity is subject to procedural safeguards imposed by the govern-
ment, or to direct government agency review of its decisions."' Private quasi-
judicial decision-making is less objectionable if there is an articulated formal
and fair procedure for decision-making within the entity and access to a
government body that can fully review the private decision. In all of these cases
a common theme is discernible: delegation to private entities is permissible on-
ly if there are assurances of fair private decision-making and ultimate control
by accountable government entities.
Judged by these standards the current extent of delegation of federal
authority to JCAH under the Medicare program is highly questionable. The
law does not merely adopt pre-existing JCAH accreditation standards, but
rather permits hospital accreditation to serve as a basis for Medicare certifica-
tion of general hospitals,
598
and further, requires accreditation for psychiatric
hospitals under some circumstances,
599
regardless of future changes by JCAH
in its standards. The Medicare legislation not only allows the hospital industry
the choice of accepting or rejecting FIHS certification standards but also per-
mits the industry, as an alternative, to comply with standards established by
itself through JCAH. The Medicare statute provides no standards to guide
JCAH in creating its standards and imposes on JCAH no internal procedural
safeguards to protect persons applying for or contesting the grant of accredita-
tion.
445 (1979),
appeal dismissed,
299 N.C. 545, 265 S.E.2d 404 (1980).
See also,
finding insufficient
standards, Bayside Timber Company v. Board of Supervisors, 20 Cal. App. 3d 1, 97 Cal. Rptr.
431 (1971); Jennings v. Exeter-West Greenwich Regional School Dist. Committee, 116 R.I.
190, 352 A.2d 634 (1976).
595
Potter v. New Jersey Supreme Court, 403 F. Supp. 1036 (D.N.J. 1975); Natural
Milk Producers Ass'n v. City and County of San Francisco, 20 Cal. 2d 101, 124 P.2d 25 (1942);
Colorado Polytechnic College v. State Ed. of Community Colleges and Occupational Education,
173 Cola. 39, 476 P.2d 38 (1970). Other courts, however, have held that special expertise of a
private association does not in itself qualify it to assume government responsibility.
See, e.g.,
Hetherington v. McHale, 458 Pa. 479, 329 A.2d 250 (1974); Hillman v. Northern Wasco Coun-
ty Peoples Utility Dist., 213 Or. 264, 323 P.2d 664 (1957).
598
State v. Wakeen, 263 Wis. 401, 57 N.W.2d 364 (1953).
597
See, e.g.,
Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 310 U.S. 381, 399 (1940); Todd &
Co., Inc. v. SEC, 557 F.2d 1008 (3d Cir. 1977); R. J. Johnson and Co. v. FCC, 198 F.2d 690
(2d Cir. 1952),
cert. denied,
344 U.S. 855 (1952); Hogan v. State Bar, 36 Cal. 2d 807, 228 P.2d
554 (1951); People v. Chicago R.R. Terminal Auth., 14 III. 2d 230, 151 N.E.2d 311 (1958);
Podiatry Soc'y of N.Y. v. Regents, 78 Misc. 2d 731, 358 N.Y.S.2d 276 (1974).
598
42 U.S.C. 1395bb (1978).
'" 42 U.S.C. 5 1395x(f), 42 U.S.C. § 1396(h) (1976).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
921
Even more important, there is no direct federal review of JCAH decisions.
The decision to grant accreditation is only reviewable by HHS through its re-
tained power to deny certification if a subsequent verification investigation is
made and shows substantial non-compliance with the Medicare Act and stand-
ards,60o a power HHS has never exercised."' A JCAH decision to deny a gen-
eral hospital accreditation is only reviewable to the extent that HHS may inde-
pendently certify a non-accredited facility for participation in the Medicare
program. JCAH psychiatric facility accreditation decisions have a final and un-
reviewable effect on Medicaid certification — except insofar as distinct part
certification may provide relief.
6
°
2
A review of the history of the delegation of federal authority to JCAH
reveals an obvious attempt by the legislature to confer benefits on the member
groups of JCAH to secure their support."' As the delegation resulted in the
creation of private' goods at the public expense, it is a suspect delegation.
604
The delegation of Medicare certification power to JCAH was even more sus-
pect prior to the 1972 Medicare amendments and was the major issue raised in
Self-help v. Richardson,
the case brought against JCAH by consumers that
precipitated the 1972 Social Security amendments."'
Leone v. Mathews
has
subsequently held there to be no unconstitutional delegation to JCAH of re-
sponsibility to certify psychiatric facilities for Medicare and Medicaid funding
where recourse to the federal government through independent distinct part
certification was available.
6
" The federal district court in
Cospito
v.
Calif
-
aria"'
has also upheld delegation to JCAH in the same context. The court relied on
cases upholding delegation of government authority where technical questions
were decided by private scientific bodies and pointed to reliance on private
educational accreditation by Congress and private drug formulas by the Food
and Drug Administration.
608
The most difficult current federal delegation
problem, the absolute power of JCAH to decide whether or not a psychiatric
facility for patients under the age of twenty-one may participate in the
Medicaid program (where distinct part certification is not available), remains
to be decided.
6
°
9
While the extensive federal delegation to JCAH is questionable, even
more substantial problems of delegation are raised in those states in which
licensing statutes grant JCAH absolute discretion in licensing decisions."'
600
See
42 U.S.C.
1396bb(b) (1976).
661
See
GAO
REPORT,
supra
note 207, at 14.
641
See supra
note 61.
600
See supra, text
accompanying notes 155-169, 588.
604
See
Aranson, Gellhorn & Robinson,
supra
note 575, at 63-67.
60
' Self-Help for the Elderly v. Richardson, No. 2016-71 (D.D.C. 1970);
see supra
text
accompanying notes 177, 178, 185.
6°6
76-1059 (D.N.J. Aug. 2, 1977).
600
No. 77-869 (D.N.J. 1983);
see also
earlier decision at 89 F.R.D. 374 (1981).
608
See
Cospito v. Califano, No. 77-869 at 18-22 (D.N.J. 1983).
600
See supra
note 61.
64
°
See supra
note 66.
922
BOSTON COLLEGE LA W REVIEW
[Vol. 24:835
Challenges to delegation may also be more successful at the state level because
the delegation doctrine has retained more vitality there than it has in the fed-
eral courts.'"
Though the delegation question has not yet arisen at the state level in re-
gard to licensing, it has been raised in another context. In the late 1960's and
early 1970's many state statutes outlawing abortion were amended to permit
abortions but only in JCAH accredited facilities. This legislation was chal-
lenged in a number of cases raising the question of the legality of state govern-
ments delegating to JCAH the authority to determine whether or not a facility
was appropriate to perform abortions. In
Poe v. Menghini
612
the Kansas abor-
tion statute was held to delegate legislative policy-making authority to JCAH
unconstitutionally.
People v. Barksdale,
613
on the other hand, found the same
delegation in the California statute to be unobjectionable.
Doe v. Bolton
614
held
the JCAH accreditation requirement unconstitutional on equal protection
grounds rather than on delegation grounds: the court decided states could not
limit abortions to JCAH accredited facilities if they imposed no such limita-
tions on other similar medical procedures.'''
Though the 1972 amendments to the Medicare law brought about the dis-
missal of the
Self-help
case and rendered the delegation of federal certification
authority to JCAH less suspect, certain specific changes could be made within
the Medicare program that would address the concerns of accountability and
fairness that support the non-delegation doctrine, and thus render the delega-
tion of authority to JCAH less subject to constitutional attack. These changes
would also clarify JCAH's status under the APA and assure due process for
those affected by the JCAH. First, HHS ought to take seriously its authority to
create standards in excess of those promulgated by JCAH. Second, the valida-
tion process ought to be restructured to focus on monitoring closely, and where
necessary decertifying, substandard accredited hospitals. This would largely
remedy the problem of the absence of any direct review mechanism for ques-
tionable accreditation decisions. Finally, the Social Security legislation ought
to be amended to permit direct administrative and judicial review of accredita-
tion decisions affecting psychiatric hospitals to eliminate JCAH's unreviewable
discretion in this area.'" Direct review of accreditation decisions affecting the
Medicare or Medicaid status of general hospitals, which could be initiated by
affected hospital staff or employees or patients ought also to be considered.
611
Note,
The State Courts and Delegation, supra
note 582, at 1398.
612
F. Supp. 986 (D. Kan. 1972).
613
Cal. 3d 320, 503 P.2d 257, 105 Cal. Rptr. 1 (1972).
614
U.S. 179 (1973).
614
Id.
at 193-95.
616
This is a change JCAH has itself advocated, telephone interview with Eleanor
Wagner, Daniel Schuyler and Paul Mullen of JCAH (December 10, 1982).
July 1983]
PRIVATE REGULATION OF HEALTH CARE
923
CONCLUSION
We began by considering the two models currently being debated as
means for protecting the public's interest in health care: market reform to pro-
mote competition and command and control government regulation. It may
come as a surprise that JCAH, the entity that has actually developed for pro-
tecting the public's interest in institutional medical care quality, is a private
non-government regulator and fits neither of these models. Yet, considering
the economic interests of its constituencies, it is
quite
easy to understand why
JCAH exists, and why it functions as well (and as poorly) as it does in protect-
ing the public interest.
The JCAH, as a private regulator, has had a significant impact on the
development of institutional medical care in America, and continues to play a
major role in determining the nature of that care. Private standardization and
certification as means of regulation have received strong support from the cur-
rent administration. The potential, and problems, of private standardization
and certification are illuminated by the JCAH experience. This article's anal-
ysis of that experience suggests that private entities be used as regulators only
with the utmost care, with consideration of the nature and interests of the
private regulator and of the adequacy of legal remedies for the problems that
private regulation may cause.